The Solow–Swan model was an extension to the 1946 Harrod–Domar model that dropped the restrictive assumption that only capital contributes to growth (so long as there is sufficient labor to use all capital). Important contributions to the model came from the work done by Solow and by Swan in 1956, who independently developed relatively simple growth models.[2][3] Solow's model fitted available data on US economic growth with some success.[6] In 1987 Solow was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for his work. Today, economists use Solow's sources-of-growth accounting to estimate the separate effects on economic growth of technological change, capital, and labor.[7]
The Solow model is also one of the most widely used models in economics to explain economic growth.[8] Basically, it asserts that outcomes on the "total factor productivity (TFP) can lead to limitless increases in the standard of living in a country."[8]
Extension to the Harrod–Domar model
Solow extended the Harrod–Domar model by adding labor as a factor of production and capital-output ratios that are not fixed as they are in the Harrod–Domar model. These refinements allow increasing capital intensity to be distinguished from technological progress. Solow sees the fixed proportions production function as a "crucial assumption" to the instability results in the Harrod-Domar model. His own work expands upon this by exploring the implications of alternative specifications, namely the Cobb–Douglas and the more general constant elasticity of substitution (CES).[2] Although this has become the canonical and celebrated story[9] in the history of economics, featured in many economic textbooks,[10] recent reappraisal of Harrod's work has contested it. One central criticism is that Harrod's original piece[11] was neither mainly concerned with economic growth nor did he explicitly use a fixed proportions production function.[10][12]
Long-run implications
A standard Solow model predicts that in the long run, economies converge to their balanced growth equilibrium and that permanent growth of per capita income is achievable only through technological progress. Both shifts in saving and in population growth cause only level effects in the long-run (i.e. in the absolute value of real income per capita).
An interesting implication of Solow's model is that poor countries should grow faster and eventually catch-up to richer countries. This convergence could be explained by:[13]
Lags in the diffusion on knowledge. Differences in real income might shrink as poor countries receive better technology and information;
Efficient allocation of international capital flows, since the rate of return on capital should be higher in poorer countries. In practice, this is seldom observed and is known as Lucas' paradox;
A mathematical implication of the model (assuming poor countries have not yet reached their steady state).
Baumol attempted to verify this empirically and found a very strong correlation between a countries' output growth over a long period of time (1870 to 1979) and its initial wealth.[14] His findings were later contested by DeLong who claimed that both the non-randomness of the sampled countries, and potential for significant measurement errors for estimates of real income per capita in 1870, biased Baumol's findings. DeLong concludes that there is little evidence to support the convergence theory.
Assumptions
The key assumption of the Solow–Swan growth model is that capital is subject to diminishing returns in a closed economy.
Given a fixed stock of labor, the impact on output of the last unit of capital accumulated will always be less than the one before.
Assuming for simplicity no technological progress or labor force growth, diminishing returns implies that at some point the amount of new capital produced is only just enough to make up for the amount of existing capital lost due to depreciation.[1] At this point, because of the assumptions of no technological progress or labor force growth, we can see the economy ceases to grow.
Assuming non-zero rates of labor growth complicate matters somewhat, but the basic logic still applies[2] – in the short-run, the rate of growth slows as diminishing returns take effect and the economy converges to a constant "steady-state" rate of growth (that is, no economic growth per-capita).
Including non-zero technological progress is very similar to the assumption of non-zero workforce growth, in terms of "effective labor": a new steady state is reached with constant output per worker-hour required for a unit of output. However, in this case, per-capita output grows at the rate of technological progress in the "steady-state"[3] (that is, the rate of productivity growth).
Variations in the effects of productivity
In the Solow–Swan model the unexplained change in the growth of output after accounting for the effect of capital accumulation is called the Solow residual. This residual measures the exogenous increase in total factor productivity (TFP) during a particular time period. The increase in TFP is often attributed entirely to technological progress, but it also includes any permanent improvement in the efficiency with which factors of production are combined over time. Implicitly TFP growth includes any permanent productivity improvements that result from improved management practices in the private or public sectors of the economy. Paradoxically, even though TFP growth is exogenous in the model, it cannot be observed, so it can only be estimated in conjunction with the simultaneous estimate of the effect of capital accumulation on growth during a particular time period.
The model can be reformulated in slightly different ways using different productivity assumptions, or different measurement metrics:
Average Labor Productivity (ALP) is economic output per labor hour.
Multifactor productivity (MFP) is output divided by a weighted average of capital and labor inputs. The weights used are usually based on the aggregate input shares either factor earns. This ratio is often quoted as: 33% return to capital and 67% return to labor (in Western nations).
In a growing economy, capital is accumulated faster than people are born, so the denominator in the growth function under the MFP calculation is growing faster than in the ALP calculation. Hence, MFP growth is almost always lower than ALP growth. (Therefore, measuring in ALP terms increases the apparent capital deepening effect.) MFP is measured by the "Solow residual", not ALP.
where denotes time, is the elasticity of output with respect to capital, and represents total production. refers to labor-augmenting technology or “knowledge”, thus represents effective labor. All factors of production are fully employed, and initial values , , and are given. The number of workers, i.e. labor, as well as the level of technology grow exogenously at rates and , respectively:
The number of effective units of labor, , therefore grows at rate . Meanwhile, the stock of capital depreciates over time at a constant rate . However, only a fraction of the output ( with ) is consumed, leaving a saved share for investment. This dynamic is expressed through the following differential equation:
where is shorthand for , the derivative with respect to time. Derivative with respect to time means that it is the change in capital stock—output that is neither consumed nor used to replace worn-out old capital goods is net investment.
Since the production function has constant returns to scale, it can be written as output per effective unit of labour, which is a measure for wealth creation:[note 2]
The main interest of the model is the dynamics of capital intensity, the capital stock per unit of effective labour. Its behaviour over time is given by the key equation of the Solow–Swan model:[note 3]
The first term, , is the actual investment per unit of effective labour: the fraction of the output per unit of effective labour that is saved and invested. The second term, , is the “break-even investment”: the amount of investment that must be invested to prevent from falling.[17]: 16 The equation implies that converges to a steady-state value of , defined by , at which there is neither an increase nor a decrease of capital intensity:
at which the stock of capital and effective labour are growing at rate . Likewise, it is possible to calculate the steady-state of created wealth that corresponds with :
By assumption of constant returns, output is also growing at that rate. In essence, the Solow–Swan model predicts that an economy will converge to a balanced-growth equilibrium, regardless of its starting point. In this situation, the growth of output per worker is determined solely by the rate of technological progress.[17]: 18
Since, by definition, , at the equilibrium we have
Therefore, at the equilibrium, the capital/output ratio depends only on the saving, growth, and depreciation rates. This is the Solow–Swan model's version of the golden rule saving rate.
Since , at any time the marginal product of capital in the Solow–Swan model is inversely related to the capital/labor ratio.
If productivity is the same across countries, then countries with less capital per worker have a higher marginal product, which would provide a higher return on capital investment. As a consequence, the model predicts that in a world of open market economies and global financial capital, investment will flow from rich countries to poor countries, until capital/worker and income/worker equalize across countries.
Since the marginal product of physical capital is not higher in poor countries than in rich countries,[18] the implication is that productivity is lower in poor countries. The basic Solow model cannot explain why productivity is lower in these countries. Lucas suggested that lower levels of human capital in poor countries could explain the lower productivity.[19]
so that is the fraction of income appropriated by capital. Thus, the Solow–Swan model assumes from the beginning that the labor-capital split of income is constant.
Mankiw–Romer–Weil version of model
Addition of human capital
In 1992, N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer, and David N. Weil theorised a version of the Solow-Swan model, augmented to include a role for human capital, that can explain the failure of international investment to flow to poor countries.[20] In this model output and the marginal product of capital (K) are lower in poor countries because they have less human capital than rich countries.
Similar to the textbook Solow–Swan model, the production function is of Cobb–Douglas type:
where is the stock of human capital, which depreciates at the same rate as physical capital. For simplicity, they assume the same function of accumulation for both types of capital. Like in Solow–Swan, a fraction of the outcome, , is saved each period, but in this case split up and invested partly in physical and partly in human capital, such that . Therefore, there are two fundamental dynamic equations in this model:
The balanced (or steady-state) equilibrium growth path is determined by , which means and . Solving for the steady-state level of and yields:
In the steady state, .
Econometric estimates
Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare cast doubt on the validity of the augmented model because Mankiw, Romer, and Weil's estimates of did not seem consistent with accepted estimates of the effect of increases in schooling on workers' salaries. Though the estimated model explained 78% of variation in income across countries, the estimates of implied that human capital's external effects on national income are greater than its direct effect on workers' salaries.[21]
Accounting for external effects
Theodore Breton provided an insight that reconciled the large effect of human capital from schooling in the Mankiw, Romer and Weil model with the smaller effect of schooling on workers' salaries. He demonstrated that the mathematical properties of the model include significant external effects between the factors of production, because human capital and physical capital are multiplicative factors of production.[22] The external effect of human capital on the productivity of physical capital is evident in the marginal product of physical capital:
He showed that the large estimates of the effect of human capital in cross-country estimates of the model are consistent with the smaller effect typically found on workers' salaries when the external effects of human capital on physical capital and labor are taken into account. This insight significantly strengthens the case for the Mankiw, Romer, and Weil version of the Solow–Swan model. Most analyses criticizing this model fail to account for the pecuniary external effects of both types of capital inherent in the model.[22]
Total factor productivity
The exogenous rate of TFP (total factor productivity) growth in the Solow–Swan model is the residual after accounting for capital accumulation. The Mankiw, Romer, and Weil model provide a lower estimate of the TFP (residual) than the basic Solow–Swan model because the addition of human capital to the model enables capital accumulation to explain more of the variation in income across countries. In the basic model, the TFP residual includes the effect of human capital because human capital is not included as a factor of production.
Conditional convergence
The Solow–Swan model augmented with human capital predicts that the income levels of poor countries will tend to catch up with or converge towards the income levels of rich countries if the poor countries have similar savings rates for both physical capital and human capital as a share of output, a process known as conditional convergence. However, savings rates vary widely across countries. In particular, since considerable financing constraints exist for investment in schooling, savings rates for human capital are likely to vary as a function of cultural and ideological characteristics in each country.[23]
Since the 1950s, output/worker in rich and poor countries generally has not converged, but those poor countries that have greatly raised their savings rates have experienced the income convergence predicted by the Solow–Swan model. As an example, output/worker in Japan, a country which was once relatively poor, has converged to the level of the rich countries. Japan experienced high growth rates after it raised its savings rates in the 1950s and 1960s, and it has experienced slowing growth of output/worker since its savings rates stabilized around 1970, as predicted by the model.
The per-capita income levels of the southern states of the United States have tended to converge to the levels in the Northern states. The observed convergence in these states is also consistent with the conditional convergence concept. Whether absolute convergence between countries or regions occurs depends on whether they have similar characteristics, such as:
Additional evidence for conditional convergence comes from multivariate, cross-country regressions.[25]
Econometric analysis on Singapore and the other "East Asian Tigers" has produced the surprising result that although output per worker has been rising, almost none of their rapid growth had been due to rising per-capita productivity (they have a low "Solow residual").[7]
^ abHaines, Joel D.; Sharif, Nawaz M. (2006). "A framework for managing the sophistication of the components of technology for global competition". Competitiveness Review. 16 (2): 106–121. doi:10.1108/cr.2006.16.2.106.
^ abBesomi, Daniele (2001). "Harrod's dynamics and the theory of growth: the story of a mistaken attribution". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 25 (1): 79–96. doi:10.1093/cje/25.1.79. JSTOR23599721.
^Harrod, R. F. (1939). "An Essay in Dynamic Theory". The Economic Journal. 49 (193): 14–33. doi:10.2307/2225181. JSTOR2225181.
^Romer, David (2006). Advanced Macroeconomics. McGraw-Hill. pp. 31–35. ISBN9780072877304.
^Baumol, William J. (1986). "Productivity Growth, Convergence, and Welfare: What the Long-Run Data Show". The American Economic Review. 76 (5): 1072–1085. JSTOR1816469.
^Litina, Anastasia; Palivos, Theodore (2008). "Do Inada conditions imply that production function must be asymptotically Cobb–Douglas? A comment". Economics Letters. 99 (3): 498–499. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2007.09.035.
^ abRomer, David (2011). "The Solow Growth Model". Advanced Macroeconomics (Fourth ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. pp. 6–48. ISBN978-0-07-351137-5.
^Breton, T. R. (2013). "The role of education in economic growth: Theory, history and current returns". Educational Research. 55 (2): 121–138. doi:10.1080/00131881.2013.801241. S2CID154380029.
Agénor, Pierre-Richard (2004). "Growth and Technological Progress: The Solow–Swan Model". The Economics of Adjustment and Growth (Second ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press. pp. 439–462. ISBN978-0-674-01578-4.
For other uses, see Arad (disambiguation). For the archaeological site, see Tel Arad. AradKotaPopulasi23.300[1]Situs webhttp://www.arad.muni.il Ruins of ancient Tel Arad Arad (Ibrani: עֲרָד (audio)ⓘ; Arab: عرادcode: ar is deprecated ) adalah sebuah kota yang terletak di Distrik Selatan dari Israel. Kota ini terletak pada perbatasan Negev dan Judean Deserts, 25 kilometer (15,5 mi) sebelah barat dari Laut Mati dan 45 kilometer (28,0 mi) sebelah timur dari kota Beers...
Ardito Wijaya Wakil Bupati Lampung Tengah ke-6PetahanaMulai menjabat 26 Februari 2021PresidenJoko WidodoGubernurArinal DjunaidiBupatiMusa Ahmad PendahuluLoekman DjoyosoemartoPenggantiPetahana Informasi pribadiLahir23 Januari 1980 (umur 44)Bandar Jaya, LampungKebangsaanIndonesiaPartai politikPKBSuami/istriIndria SudrajatAlma materUniversitas TrisaktiSunting kotak info • L • B dr. H. Ardito Wijaya (lahir 23 Januari 1980) adalah Wakil Bupati Kabupaten Lampung Tengah pe...
كأس العالم الشاطئية 2007 تفاصيل الموسم كأس العالم الشاطئية النسخة 3 البلد البرازيل التاريخ بداية:2 نوفمبر 2006 نهاية:11 نوفمبر 2006 المنظم الاتحاد الدولي لكرة القدم البطل منتخب البرازيل لكرة القدم الشاطئية مباريات ملعوبة 32 عدد المشاركين 16 أهداف...
Jernang dari Daemonorops draco, gerusan halus (kiri) dan resin beku (kanan) Rotan jernang Daemonorops draco, pelat botani dari Kohler (1897) Jernang adalah sejenis resin yang dihasilkan dari beberapa spesies rotan dari genus Daemonorops. Resin berwarna merah ini telah sejak lama diperdagangkan dan dimanfaatkan sebagai bahan pewarna, dupa, dan bahan obat tradisional. Terutama dihasilkan dari Sumatra dan Kalimantan, sebutannya dalam berbagai daerah di antaranya adalah jernang, jerenang, jeranan...
Artikel ini bukan mengenai Need for Speed: Most Wanted (permainan video 2005). Need for Speed: Most Wanted Sampul Need for Speed: Most WantedTipevideo game reboot (en) BerdasarkanNeed for Speed: Most Wanted Versi pertamaMicrosoft Windows, PlayStation 3, PS Vita, Xbox 360, iOS, Android, Kindle FireNA: 30 October 2012AU: 1 November 2012EU: 2 November 2012Wii U[1]NA: 19 March 2013AU: 21 March 2013[2]EU: 22 March 2013GenreBalapanLatar tempatNeed for Speed universe (en) Bahasa Daft...
Laura SiegemundSiegemund di AS Terbuka 2016Nama lengkapLaura Natalie Siegemund[1]Kebangsaan JermanTempat tinggalStuttgart, JermanLahir04 Maret 1988 (umur 36)Filderstadt, Jerman BaratTinggi168 cm (5 ft 6 in)[2]Total hadiahUS$ 1.491.715[2]TunggalRekor (M–K)408–262 (60.9%)Gelar2 WTA, 11 ITF[2]Peringkat tertinggiNo. 27 (29 Agustus 2016)Peringkat saat iniNo. 30 (1 Mei 2017)GandaRekor (M–K)203–130 (60.96%)Gelar3 WTA, 20 ITFPeringkat t...
Politics of São Tomé and Príncipe Constitution Human rights LGBT rights Executive President Carlos Vila Nova Government Prime Minister Patrice Trovoada Council of Ministers Legislature National Assembly President: Jose da Graca Diogo Judiciary Supreme Court of Justice Elections Recent elections Presidential: 20162021 Legislative: 20182022 Political parties Administrative divisions Autonomous Region of Príncipe Districts Foreign relations Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Cooperation and Commun...
هنودمعلومات عامةنسبة التسمية الهند التعداد الكليالتعداد قرابة 1.21 مليار[1][2]تعداد الهند عام 2011ق. 1.32 مليار[3]تقديرات عام 2017ق. 30.8 مليون[4]مناطق الوجود المميزةبلد الأصل الهند البلد الهند الهند نيبال 4,000,000[5] الولايات المتحدة 3,982,398[6] الإمار...
Ця стаття потребує додаткових посилань на джерела для поліпшення її перевірності. Будь ласка, допоможіть удосконалити цю статтю, додавши посилання на надійні (авторитетні) джерела. Зверніться на сторінку обговорення за поясненнями та допоможіть виправити недоліки. Мат...
Hünenberg Hünenberg gemeinde de Suiza Escudo HünenbergLocalización de Hünenberg en SuizaPaís Suiza• Cantón Cantón de ZugUbicación 47°10′34″N 8°25′35″E / 47.176111111111, 8.4263888888889• Altitud 444 mSuperficie 18,7 km²Población[1] 8841 hab. (2014)• Densidad 473 hab./km²Lengua AlemánCódigo postal 6331Sitio web Sitio web oficial[editar datos en Wikidata] Hünenberg es una comuna suiz...
American film director This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Scott Sidney – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (May 2019) (Learn how and when to remove this message) Scott SidneySidney in 1921BornHarry Wilbur Siggins1872DiedJuly 20, 1928London, UK Scott Sidney (1872 – 20 July 1928), ...
2017 live album by Grateful DeadDave's Picks Volume 22Live album by Grateful DeadReleasedMay 1, 2017RecordedDecember 7, 1971VenueFelt ForumNew York CityGenreRockLength295:00LabelRhinoProducerGrateful DeadGrateful Dead chronology July 29 1966, P.N.E. Garden Aud., Vancouver Canada(2017) Dave's Picks Volume 22(2017) May 1977: Get Shown the Light(2017) Alternative coverDave's Picks 2017 Bonus Disc Dave's Picks Volume 22 is a live album by the rock band the Grateful Dead. It contains the c...
19th-century U.S. Army officer For the English rugby union player, see George Crook (rugby union). General Crook redirects here. For the musician, see General Crook (musician). George CrookPortrait of George CrookNickname(s)Nantan Lupan, which means Grey Wolf; “Three Stars” to the LakotaBorn(1828-09-08)September 8, 1828Taylorsville, Ohio, USDiedMarch 21, 1890(1890-03-21) (aged 61)Chicago, Illinois, USPlace of burialArlington National CemeteryAllegianceUnited States of AmericaUnionSer...
يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم في تطوير هذه المقالة من خلال إضافة مصادر موثوق بها. أي معلومات غير موثقة يمكن التشكيك بها وإزالتها. (نوفمبر 2019) كأس الاتحاد الإنجليزي 1920–21 تفاصيل الموسم كأس الاتحاد الإنجليزي النسخة 46 البلد المملكة المتحدة ...
Rome metro station Due Leoni-Fontana CandidaGeneral informationCoordinates41°51′54″N 12°39′29″E / 41.864907°N 12.658093°E / 41.864907; 12.658093Owned byATACConstructionStructure typeat-gradeParkingyesHistoryOpened9 November 2014; 9 years ago (2014-11-09)Services Preceding station Rome Metro Following station Grotte Celonitowards San Giovanni Line C Borghesianatowards Monte Compatri-Pantano LocationClick on the map to see marker Due Leoni-F...
Chilean island in the Pacific For the Kris Kristofferson album, see Easter Island (album). Rapa Nui redirects here. For other uses, see Rapa Nui (disambiguation). This article should specify the language of its non-English content, using {{lang}}, {{transliteration}} for transliterated languages, and {{IPA}} for phonetic transcriptions, with an appropriate ISO 639 code. Wikipedia's multilingual support templates may also be used. See...
BećaracSlavonski bećari ensemble in 1997Stylistic originsCroatian musicCultural originsSlavonia Bećarac singing and playing from Eastern CroatiaUNESCO Intangible Cultural HeritageCountryCroatiaReference00358RegionEurope and North AmericaInscription historyInscription2011 (6th session)ListRepresentative Bećarac is a humorous form of folk song, originally from rural Slavonia, Croatia and eventually spreading into southern Hungary and the Vojvodina region of Serbia. The root of the word come...