Property rights are constructs in economics for determining how a resource or economic good is used and owned,[1] which have developed over ancient and modern history, from Abrahamic law to Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights. Resources can be owned by (and hence be the property of) individuals, associations, collectives, or governments.[2]
Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good. This attribute has three broad components,[3][4][5] and is often referred to as a bundle of rights in the United States:[6]
the right to use the good
the right to earn income from the good
the right to transfer the good to others, alter it, abandon it, or destroy it (the right to ownership cessation)
Economists such as Adam Smith stress that the expectation of profit from "improving one's stock of capital" rests on the concept of private property rights.[7]
Conceptualizing property in economics vs. law
The fields of economics and law do not have a general consensus on conceptions of property rights.[8] Various property types are used in law but the terminology can be seen in economic reports. Sometimes in economics, property types are simply described as private or public/common in reference to private goods (excludable and rivalrous goods like a phone),[9] as well as public goods (non-excludable and non-rivalrous goods, like air),[10] respectively.[11] Below is a list of the several property types defined and their relation to the economic concepts of excludability (the ability to limit the consumption of the good) and rivalry (a person's consumption of the good reduces the ability of another to consume it).
Types of property regimes
Property rights can be categorized with excludability and rivalry. Excludability describes the characteristic regarding whether a good can be withheld from certain consumers. In terms of the same good, rivalry describes its accessibility to competing consumers. The combination of excludability and rivalry as parameters is reflected through various types of property rights.
Open-access property is owned by nobody (res nullius).[12] It is non-excludable, as excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly, and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous. Open-access property is not managed by anyone, and access to it is not controlled. This is also known as a common property resource, impure public good or sometimes erroneously as a common pool resource.[13] A common pool resource however is often managed the group of people that have access to that resource [14]. Examples of this can be air, water, sights, and sounds. Tragedy of the commons refers to this title. An example would be unregulated forests as there's limited resources available and therefore rivalrous, but anyone may access these resources. If non-rivalrous, it would be a public good (cannot be rivalrous, no matter how much it is used, for example, the ocean (outside of territorial borders)).[10]
Open-access property may exist because ownership has never been established, granted, by laws within a particular country, or because no effective controls are in place, or feasible, i.e., the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits.
— Encyclopedia of Law and Economics
Public property, also known as state property, is excludable and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous.[15] This type of property is publicly owned, but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority.[16] For example, a government pavement is non-excludable as anyone may use it but rivalrous as, the more people using it, the more likely it will be too crowded for another to join. Public property is sometimes used interchangeably with public good,[17] usually impure public goods. They may also be a club good, which is excludable and non-rivalrous.[18] An example would be paying to go to an uncongested public bathroom, as the price excludes those who can't afford it but there is ample utilities for more people to use making it non-rivalrous.
Private property is both excludable and rivalrous. Private property access, use, exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners.[9] This is sometimes used interchangeably with private good.[17] An example would be a cellphone as it only one person may use it, making it rivalrous, and it has to be purchased, which makes it excludable.
Common property or collective property is excludable and rivalrous. Not to be confused with common property in reference to economics, this is in reference to law. It is property that is owned by a group of individuals where access, use, and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners.[19][12] Unlike private property, common property has multiple owners, which allows for a greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement. This would still be related to private goods. An example of common property would be any private good that is jointly owned.
Property-rights theory
Introduction
Property rights theory is an exploration of how providing stakeholders with ownership of any factors of production or goods, not just land, will increase the efficiency of an economy as the gains from providing the rights exceed the costs.[20] A widely accepted explanation is that well-enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities, such as investment, innovation and trade, which lead to a more efficient market.[21] Implicit or explicit property rights can be created through government regulation in the market, either through prescriptive command and control approaches (e.g. limits on input/output/discharge quantities, specified processes/equipment, audits) or by market-based instruments (e.g. taxes, transferable permits or quotas),[19] and more recently through cooperative, self-regulatory, post-regulatory and reflexive law approaches.[22] In economics, depending on the level of transaction costs, various forms of property rights institutions will develop.[17] In economics, an institution is defined thusly:
a complex of positions, roles, norms and values lodged in particular types of social structures and organising relatively stable patterns of human activity with respect to fundamental problems in producing life-sustaining resources, in reproducing individuals, and in sustaining viable societal structures within a given environment.
— Johnathon Turner, The Institutional Order
For specificity in the case of economic property rights, this is a system or structure that has value and stability. Transaction costs are the costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights.[23][24]
Exploration
Ronald Coase proposed that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and rely on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future.[25] He asserts transaction costs are ideally zero because they cause inefficiencies; due to those who would be allocatively efficient with the ownership being unable to afford or receiving less private benefit than they gain from it, as the transaction costs on top of the cost of purchasing and maintaining the property.[26] This is known as Coase theorem. Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits, that owners will have perfect information, that scale economies are manageable, transaction costs are bearable, and that legal frameworks operate efficiently.[19]
John Locke, Adam Smith, and Karl Marx are classical economists that generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development, and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition.[27] Locke supposed that one's labour was their own property and, consequently, property was any land maintained and sustained through one's own labour as long as there was sufficient and similar quality land to meet the needs of everyone's labour.[28][29] Using this ideology, property in a broader sense would be taken as any good a person produced or maintains with their own labour. This was later elaborated on by Smith, who believed that the amount of labour it takes to produce a good does not provide its value but instead the labour the good commands or the value of goods people will be willing to trade for the good.[30] He felt the division of labour to produce products for others was better for the whole of society.[31] This was later critiqued by Marx.[29]
Sanford Grossman, Oliver Hart, and John Hardman Moore developed the property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the paradigm of incomplete contracts. These authors argue that in the real world, contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world.[32][33] There will be renegotiations in the future, so parties have insufficient investment incentives (since they will only get a fraction of the investment's return in future negotiations); i.e., there is a hold-up problem.[32][33] Hence, they argue property rights matter because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached. In other words, property rights determine the parties' future bargaining positions (while their bargaining powers, i.e. their fractions of the renegotiation surplus, are independent of the property rights allocation).[34] The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms. Yet, it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization.[35][36] The property rights approach has been extended in many directions. For instance, some authors have studied different bargaining solutions,[37][38] while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information.[39]
Three important criteria for efficiency of property rights are
(1) universality—all scarce
resources are owned by someone;
(2) exclusivity—property rights are
exclusive rights;
(3) transferability—to ensure that resources can be allocated from low to high yield uses
— Joseph Mahoney, Economic Foundations of Strategy, pg 109
Benefits of implementing property rights
One benefit of implementing property rights is that opportunism is discouraged, as it is harder to exploit a good protected by enforced property rights.[40] For example, a song can be easily pirated from purchased copies and, with no punishment, this form of the free-rider problem likely occurs. This causes the price mechanism to be less effective at finding the true market equilibrium and hurts the owners of the good who did not get it through opportunism.[41]
Another benefit is that the moral hazard is less likely to influence the actions of consumers, meaning they will be less likely to exploit resources unsustainably or inefficiently as property is protected.[42] This will lead to a lower group cost overall as people will not be able to exploit these resources as easily, causing less inefficiency issues. For example, if a person's car doesn't have property rights, people will be more likely to mistreat it or steal it for a drive, as there is no real repercussions for doing so.
Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources.[43] Empirically, using historical data of former European colonies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions – those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity – lead to economic prosperity.[44]
Real-world interconnectivity
As a nation grows the necessity for well-defined property rights grows as well.[45] This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else. Additionally, property rights are foundational for a capitalist system, allowing for growth and wealth creation.[46]
North, Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites' rent-seeking activities.[47] Particularly, the legal and political systems that protect elites' claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so-called "limited access order", in which non-elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges. In a historical study of medieval England, for instance, North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites' interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century. In contrast, the modern "open access order", which consists of a democratic political system and a free- market economy, usually features widespread, secure and impersonal property rights.[48] Universal property rights, along with impersonal economic and political competition, downplay the role of rent-seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy.
In 2013, researchers produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes: (a) reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest, and (b) improvements in household welfare; the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries. They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes, including better management of natural resources.[49]
Incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions. When instead, the state is entrusted the power to protect property, it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process.[50] The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship, originated from the seminal contribution by Guido Calabresi and Douglas Melamed.[51]
Calabresi and Melamed argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade, legalized private expropriation in the form of, for instance, liability rules can be welfare-increasing. To elaborate, when property is fully protected, some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs. When the protection of property is weak instead, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. Hence, a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers' valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low-valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights. Crucially, this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions. These data measure "horizontal property rights" and thus the extent of protection of property from "direct and indirect private takings", which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites, which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature.[51] To capture preference diversity, the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity, which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations, such as preferences.[52] Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners' property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest. Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal.[52]
^Alchian, Armen A. "Property Rights". New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition (2008). A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good.
^ abSandmo, Agnar (1989), Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter (eds.), "Public Goods", Allocation, Information and Markets, The New Palgrave, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 254–266, doi:10.1007/978-1-349-20215-7_26, ISBN978-1-349-20215-7, retrieved 2021-04-26
^Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James (2005). "Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth". Handbook of Economic Growth. 1: 397.
^See literature on post-regulatory approaches and reflexive law, especially literature from Gunther Teubner. See also the example of the 'conservation property right'
^Besley, Timothy; Maitreesh, Ghatak (2009). Rodrik, Dani; Rosenzweig, Mark R (eds.). "Property Rights and Economic Development". Handbook of Development Economics. V: 4526–28.
^ abGronow, Jukka (2016-01-01), "John Locke, Adam Smith and Karl Marx's Critique of Private Property", On the Formation of Marxism, BRILL, pp. 225–251, doi:10.1163/9789004306653_017, ISBN978-90-04-30665-3
^Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks". Journal of Public Economics. 94 (3–4): 258–268. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009.
^Meza, David de; Lockwood, Ben (1998). "Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers? Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 113 (2): 361–386. doi:10.1162/003355398555621. ISSN0033-5533.
^Chiu, Y. Stephen (1998). "Noncooperative Bargaining, Hostages, and Optimal Asset Ownership". The American Economic Review. 88 (4): 882–901. JSTOR117010.
^Schmitz, Patrick W (2006). "Information Gathering, Transaction Costs, and the Property Rights Approach". American Economic Review. 96 (1): 422–434. doi:10.1257/000282806776157722. S2CID154717219.
^Alchian, Armen A (1965). "Some Economics of Property Rights". II Politico. 30 (4): 816–829.
^Demsetz, Harold (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights". American Economic Association. 57: 347–359.
^North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2006). "A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history". National Bureau of Economic Research. 12795: 32–33.
^North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2009). "Violence and the Rise of Open-Access Orders". Journal of Democracy. 20 (1): 55–68. doi:10.1353/jod.0.0060. S2CID153774943.
^Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler-Vidra, October 2012, Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights, Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services (EPS PEAKS)https://partnerplatform.org/?tcafmd80
^Besley, Timothy, and Maitreesh Ghatak (2010). Handbook of Development Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier. pp. 4525–4595.
^ abMenozzi, Paolo; Piazza, Alberto; Cavalli-Sforza, L. Luca (1994). The History and Geography of Human Genes. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN9780691187266.
Banera Chaetodon ornatissimus Status konservasiRisiko rendahIUCN165641 TaksonomiKerajaanAnimaliaFilumChordataKelasActinopteriOrdoChaetodontiformesFamiliChaetodontidaeGenusChaetodonSpesiesChaetodon ornatissimus Cuvier, 1831 lbs Banera[2] ( Chaetodon ornatissimus ), atau ikan kupu- kupu badut adalah spesies ikan bersirip pari laut, ikan kupu-kupu dalam keluarga Chaetodontidae . Ikan banera adalah ikan yang berkerabat dekat dengan ikan kepe-kepe ( C. reticulatus ) dan ikan kepe-kepe berg...
Ermi Widyatno Kepala Kepolisian Daerah Sulawesi TengahMasa jabatan8 April 2018 – 22 Januari 2019 PendahuluI Ketut ArgawaPenggantiLukman Wahyu HariyantoWakil Kepala Kepolisian Daerah RiauMasa jabatan23 September 2016 – 8 April 2018 PendahuluSuharsonoPenggantiH.E. Permadi Informasi pribadiLahir19 April 1962 (umur 61)IndonesiaSuami/istriPeni KadarsihAnakRikfigati NetrodyaniZahratika RahmadyaniMuchammad Noorbuwono Erchaka PutroAlma materAkademi Kepolisian (1987)Karier m...
KedungrejoDesaKantor Desa KedungrejoPeta lokasi Desa KedungrejoNegara IndonesiaProvinsiJawa TimurKabupatenBanyuwangiKecamatanMuncarKode pos68472Kode Kemendagri35.10.05.2002 Luas6.64 km2Jumlah penduduk14,500 jiwaKepadatan4,071.99 jiwa/km2 Kedungrejo adalah sebuah desa di Kecamatan Muncar, Kabupaten Banyuwangi, Jawa Timur, Indonesia. Mayoritas penduduk Desa Kedungrejo adalah nelayan karena wilayah ini langsung bersentuhan dengan pesisir laut kota Muncar. Kawasan ini adalah salah satu pusat...
Artikel ini bukan mengenai Panei Tongah. Kerajaan TongaPuleʻanga Fakatuʻi ʻo Tonga (Tonga)Kingdom of Tonga (Inggris) Bendera Lambang Semboyan: Ko e Otua mo Tonga ko hoku tofi'a (Indonesia: Tuhan dan Tonga adalah Warisanku)Lagu kebangsaan: Ko e fasi 'o e tu'i 'o e 'Otu Tonga (Indonesia: Lagu Raja Kepulauan Tonga) Perlihatkan BumiPerlihatkan peta Bendera Ibu kota(dan kota terbesar)Nuku'alofa21°8′S 175°12′W / 21.133°S 175.200°W / -21.133; -175.200Bah...
Cet article possède des paronymes, voir Liguori et Ligure. Ligurie Héraldique Drapeau Administration Pays Italie Chef-lieu Gênes Provinces 4 Communes 235 Président Mandat Giovanni Toti (C!) 2020-2025 NUTS 1 ITC (Italie du nord-ouest) ISO 3166-2 IT-42 Démographie Population 1 537 094 hab. (30/04/2020) Densité 284 hab./km2 Géographie Superficie 542 100 ha = 5 421 km2 Localisation Liens Site web regione.liguria.it modifier La régio...
PerusahaanABS-CBNNegaraFilipinaTokoh utama Ging Reyes (Kepala, Berita Terpadu dan Urusan Saat Ini dan Direktur Pelaksana, ABS-CBN News Channel) Claude Vitug (Kepala, Operasi Berita Terpadu) Dindo Amparo (Kepala, Grup Pengumpulan Berita Terpadu) Dondi Ocampo (Kepala, Berita, Variasi, Infotainment dan Bicara [Ekosistem 1]) Cheryl Favila (Kepala, Grup Produksi Berita Terpadu) Chi Almario-Gonzales (Kepala, Kelompok Investigasi dan Penelitian) Ces Oreña-Drilon (Kepala Konten Akuisisi, Ekosistem G...
Akkadian ruler (2217–2193 BC) Shar-Kali-Sharri𒀭𒊬𒂵𒉌 𒈗𒌷King of AkkadKing of SumerImpression of a cylinder seal of the time of Akkadian King Sharkalisharri, with central inscription: 𒀭𒊬𒂵𒉌 𒈗𒌷 𒁕𒈝 𒈗 𒀀𒂵𒉈𒆠 𒅁𒉌𒈗 𒁾𒊬 𒀵𒋢 DShar-kali-sharri da-num lugal a-ga-deki ibe-šarrum dub-sar arad2-su Divine Sharkalisharri, the mighty king of Agade, Ibni-Sharrum, the Scribe his servant.[1] Circa 2217-2193 BC. Louvre Museum.[2&...
Министерство природных ресурсов и экологии Российской Федерациисокращённо: Минприроды России Общая информация Страна Россия Юрисдикция Россия Дата создания 12 мая 2008 Предшественники Министерство природных ресурсов Российской Федерации (1996—1998)Министерство охраны...
艾德礼伯爵 阁下The Rt Hon. The Earl AttleeKG OM CH PC FRS联合王国首相任期1945年7月26日—1951年10月26日君主乔治六世副职赫伯特·莫里森前任温斯顿·丘吉尔继任温斯顿·丘吉尔联合王国副首相任期1942年2月19日—1945年5月23日(战时内阁)君主乔治六世首相温斯顿·丘吉尔前任职位创立继任赫伯特·莫里森反对党领袖任期1951年10月26日—1955年11月25日君主乔治六世伊丽莎白二�...
Michał Pazdan Pazdan con la maglia del Legia Varsavia nel 2018 Nazionalità Polonia Altezza 180 cm Peso 78 kg Calcio Ruolo Difensore Squadra Wieczysta Cracovia CarrieraGiovanili 2002-2004 Hutnik CracoviaSquadre di club1 2004-2007 Hutnik Cracovia? (?)2007-2012 Górnik Zabrze126 (3)2012-2015 Jagiellonia85 (3)2015-2019 Legia Varsavia83 (0)2019-2021 Ankaragücü60 (2)2021-2023 Jagiellonia41 (1)2023- Wieczysta Cracovia17 (2)Nazionale 2007-2019 ...
Військово-музичне управління Збройних сил України Тип військове формуванняЗасновано 1992Країна Україна Емблема управління Військово-музичне управління Збройних сил України — структурний підрозділ Генерального штабу Збройних сил України призначений для планува...
2014 American filmTekken 2: Kazuya's RevengeSingaporan theatrical release posterDirected byWych KaosWritten by Nicole Jones Steven Paul Based onTekkenby Bandai Namco GamesProduced by Steven Paul Pimol Srivikorn Starring Kane Kosugi Cary-Hiroyuki Tagawa Rade Šerbedžija Gary Daniels Kelly Wenham CinematographyWych KaosEdited by Vance Null Robert Ferretti Music byMisha SegalProductioncompanyCrystal Sky PicturesDistributed bySP DistributionRelease dates August 6, 2014 (2014-08-06...
Grand Prix Spanyol 1993 Lomba ke-5 dari 16 dalam Formula Satu musim 1993 Detail perlombaanTanggal 9 Mei 1993Nama resmi Gran Premio de EspañaLokasi Circuit de CatalunyaBarcelona, SpainSirkuit Permanent racing facilityPanjang sirkuit 4.747 km (2.950 mi)Jarak tempuh 65 putaran, 308.414 km (191.639 mi)Penonton 35,000Posisi polePembalap Alain Prost Williams-RenaultWaktu 1:17.809Putaran tercepatPembalap Michael Schumacher Benetton-FordWaktu 1:20.989 putaran ke-61PodiumPertama Alain Prost Williams-...
Spread Your Wings Сингл Queenс альбома News of the World Сторона «А» «Spread Your Wings» Сторона «Б» «Sheer Heart Attack» Дата выпуска 10 февраля 1978 Формат 7” Дата записи 1977 Жанр хард-рок[1] Язык английский Длительность 4:32 Композитор Джон Дикон Автор слов Джон Дикон Продюсеры Queen, Майк Стоун[англ.] Лейбл�...
This page is an archive of past discussions. Do not edit the contents of this page. If you wish to start a new discussion or revive an old one, please do so on the current talk page. Archives 2023;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 2022;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 2021;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 2020;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 2019;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec 2018;Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep...
Work by Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel This section has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page. (Learn how and when to remove these messages) This article may need to be rewritten to comply with Wikipedia's quality standards. You can help. The talk page may contain suggestions. (September 2022) This article relies excessively on references to primary sources. Please improve this article by adding secondary or tertiary sources. Find sources: Scienc...
National forest in Montana, United States Flathead National ForestThe North Fork Road located in the Flathead National Forest.LocationMontana, USANearest cityColumbia Falls, MontanaCoordinates48°02′N 113°48′W / 48.033°N 113.800°W / 48.033; -113.800Area2,404,935 acres (9,732.43 km2)[1]EstablishedFebruary 22, 1897[2]Governing bodyU.S. Forest ServiceWebsiteFlathead National Forest A trail bridge over Bear Creek The Flathead National ...
Initiation and propagation of cracks in a material due to cyclic loading Metal fatigue redirects here. For other uses, see Metal Fatigue (disambiguation). Cyclic loading redirects here. For the term for soil being liquefied as a result of stress, see Soil liquefaction. It has been suggested that Static fatigue be merged into this article. (Discuss) Proposed since August 2024. Fracture surface of an aluminium crank arm from a bicycle. The dark area (due to oil, dirt and fretting) is a slow gro...