Coase believed economists should study real-world wealth creation, in the manner of Adam Smith, stating, "It is suicidal for the field to slide into a hard science of choice, ignoring the influences of society, history, culture, and politics on the working of the economy."[2] He believed economic study should reduce emphasis on Price Theory or theoretical markets and instead focus on real markets.[3][4] He established the case for the corporation as a means to pay the costs of operating a marketplace.[3] Coase is best known for two articles: "The Nature of the Firm" (1937), which introduces the concept of transaction costs to explain the nature and limits of firms; and "The Problem of Social Cost" (1960), which suggests that well-defined property rights could overcome the problems of externalities if it were not for transaction costs (see Coase theorem). Additionally, Coase's transaction costs approach has been influential in modern organizational economics, where it was re-introduced by Oliver E. Williamson.
Biography
Ronald Harry Coase was born in Willesden, a suburb of London, on 29 December 1910. His father, Henry Joseph Coase (1884–1973) was a telegraphist for the post office, as was his mother, Rosalie Elizabeth Coase (née Giles; 1882–1972), before marriage.[5][6][7] As a child, Coase had a weakness in his legs, for which he was required to wear leg-irons. Due to this problem, he attended the school for physical defectives. At the age of 12, he was able to enter Kilburn Grammar School on scholarship. At Kilburn, he studied for the intermediate examination of the University of London as an external student in 1927–29.[8][9]
Coase then continued his studies at the University of London, enrolling as an internal student of the London School of Economics, where he took courses with Arnold Plant[8] and received a Bachelor of Commerce degree in 1932. During his undergraduate studies, Coase received the Sir Ernest Cassel Travelling Scholarship which he used to visit the University of Chicago in 1931–1932 studying with Frank Knight and Jacob Viner. Coase's colleagues would later admit that they did not remember this first visit.[10] Between 1932 and 1934, Coase was an assistant lecturer at the Dundee School of Economics and Commerce, which later became part of the University of Dundee. Subsequently, Coase was an assistant lecturer in commerce at the University of Liverpool between 1934 and 1935 before returning to London School of Economics as a member of staff until 1951 in which year he was awarded an earned doctorate in economics from the University of London. He then started to work at the University at Buffalo and retained his British citizenship after moving to the United States in the 1950s.[11] In 1958, he moved to the University of Virginia. Coase settled at the University of Chicago in 1964 and became the co-editor of the Journal of Law and Economics with Aaron Director.[12] He was also for a time a trustee of the Philadelphia Society.[13] He received the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1991.
Nearing his 100th birthday, Coase was working on a book concerning the rise of the economies of China and Vietnam.[14] In an interview, Coase explained the mission of the Coase China Society and his vision of economics and the part to be played by Chinese economists.[15][16] This became "How China Became Capitalist" (2012) co-authored with Ning Wang. Coase was honoured and received an honorary doctorate from the university at Buffalo Department of Economics in May 2012.[17]
Coase married Marian Ruth Hartung of Chicago, Illinois in Willesden, England, 7 August 1937.[6] Although they were unable to have children, they were married 75 years until her death on 17 October 2012, making him one of the longest-married Nobel Prize laureates.[4][18] Coase himself died in Chicago on 2 September 2013, at the age of 102.[19] Both are buried at Graceland Cemetery in Chicago.
He was praised across the political spectrum, with Slate calling him "one of the most distinguished economists in the world"[20] and Forbes calling him "the greatest of the many great University of Chicago economists".[21]The Washington Post called his work over eight decades "impossible to summarize" while recommending five of his papers to read.[22]
In "The Nature of the Firm" (1937), a brief but highly influential essay, Coase attempts to explain why the economy features a number of business firms instead of consisting exclusively of a multitude of independent, self-employed people who contract with one another. Given that "production could be carried on without any organization [that is, firms] at all", Coase asks, why and under what conditions should we expect firms to emerge?
Since modern firms can only emerge when an entrepreneur of some sort begins to hire people, Coase's analysis proceeds by considering the conditions under which it makes sense for an entrepreneur to seek hired help instead of contracting out for some particular task.
The traditional economic theory of the time (in the tradition of Adam Smith) suggested that, because the market is "efficient" (that is, those who are best at providing each good or service most cheaply are already doing so), it should always be cheaper to contract out than to hire.
Coase noted, however, a number of transaction costs involved in using the market; the cost of obtaining a good or service via the market actually exceeds the price of the good. Other costs, including search and information costs, bargaining costs, keeping trade secrets, and policing and enforcement costs, can all potentially add to the cost of procuring something from another party. This suggests that firms will arise which can internalise the production of goods and services required to deliver a product, thus avoiding these costs. This argument sets the stage for the later contributions by Oliver Williamson: markets and hierarchies are alternative co-ordination mechanisms for economic transactions.[23][24]
There is a natural limit to what a firm can produce internally, however. Coase notices "decreasing returns to the entrepreneur function", including increasing overhead costs and increasing propensity for an overwhelmed manager to make mistakes in resource allocation. These factors become countervailing costs to the use of the firm.
Coase argues that the size of a firm (as measured by how many contractual relations are "internal" to the firm and how many "external") is a result of finding an optimal balance between the competing tendencies of the costs outlined above. In general, making the firm larger will initially be advantageous, but the decreasing returns indicated above will eventually kick in, preventing the firm from growing indefinitely.
Other things being equal, therefore, a firm will tend to be larger:
the lower the costs of organising and the slower these costs rise with an increase in the number of transactions organised
the less likely the entrepreneur is to make mistakes and the smaller the increase in mistakes with an increase in the transactions organised
the greater the lowering (or the smaller the rise) in the supply price of factors of production to firms of larger size
The first two costs will increase with the spatial distribution of the transactions organised and the dissimilarity of the transactions. This explains why firms tend to either be in different geographic locations or to perform different functions. Additionally, technology changes that mitigate the cost of organising transactions across space may allow firms to become larger – the advent of the telephone and of cheap air travel, for example, would be expected to increase the size of firms.
A further exploration of the dichotomy between markets and hierarchies as co-ordination mechanisms for economic transactions derived a third alternative way called Commons based peer production, in which individuals successfully collaborate on large-scale projects following a diverse cluster of motivational drives and social signals.
Upon publishing his article The Federal Communications Commission in 1959, Coase received negative feedback from the faculty at the University of Chicago over his conclusions and apparent conflicts with A. C. Pigou. According to Coase, "What I said was thought to run counter to Pigou's analysis by a number of economists at the University of Chicago and was therefore, according to them, wrong. At a meeting in Chicago I was able to convince these economists that I was right and Pigou's analysis faulty." Coase had presented his paper in 1960 during a seminar in Chicago, to twenty senior economist including George Stigler and Milton Friedman. He gradually won over the usually skeptic audience, in what has later been considered a "paradigm-shifting moment" in the genesis of Chicago Law and Economics.[25] Coase would join the Chicago faculty four years later.
Published in the Journal of Law and Economics in 1960, while Coase was a member of the Economics department at the University of Virginia, "The Problem of Social Cost" provided the key insight that it is unclear where the blame for externalities lies. The example he gave was of a rancher whose cattle stray onto the cropland of his neighbour. If the rancher is made to restrict his cattle, he is harmed just as the farmer is if the cattle remain unrestrained.
Coase argued that without transaction costs the initial assignment of property rights makes no difference to whether or not the farmer and rancher can achieve the economically efficient outcome. If the cost of restraining cattle by, say, building a fence, is less than the cost of crop damage, the fence will be built. The initial assignment of property rights determines who builds the fence. If the farmer is responsible for the crop damage, the farmer will pay for the fence (as long the fence costs less than the crop damage). The allocation of property rights is primarily an equity issue, with consequences for the distribution of income and wealth, rather than an efficiency issue.
With sufficient transaction costs, initial property rights matter for both equity and efficiency. From the point of view of economic efficiency, property rights should be assigned such that the owner of the rights wants to take the economically efficient action. To elaborate, if it is efficient not to restrict the cattle, the rancher should be given the rights (so that cattle can move about freely), whereas if it is efficient to restrict the cattle, the farmer should be given the rights over the movement of the cattle (so the cattle are restricted).
This seminal argument forms the basis of the famous Coase theorem as labelled by Stigler.
In 1990, Coase wrote that he feared "The Problem of Social Cost" had been widely misunderstood.[26]
Law and economics
Though trained as an economist, Coase spent much of his career working in a law school. He is a central figure in the development of the subfield of law and economics. He viewed law and economics as having two parts, the first "using the economists' approach and concepts to analyze the working of the legal system, often called the economic analysis of the law"; and the second "a study of the influence of the legal system on the working of the economic system."[27] Coase said that the second part "is the part of law and economics in which I am most interested."
In his Simons Lecture celebrating the centennial of the University of Chicago, titled "Law and Economics at Chicago", Coase noted that he only accidentally wandered into the field:
It is generally agreed that this article has had an immense influence on legal scholarship, but this was no part of my intention. For me, 'The Problem of Social Cost' was an essay in economics. It was aimed at economists. What I wanted to do was to improve our analysis of the working of the economic system. Law came into article because, in a regime of positive transaction costs, the character of the law becomes one of the main factors determining the performance of the economy. If transaction costs were zero (as is assumed in standard economic theory) we can imagine people contracting around the law whenever the value of production would be increased by a change in the legal position. But in a regime of positive transaction costs, such contracting would not occur whenever transaction costs were greater than the gain that such a redistribution of rights would bring. As a consequence the rights which individuals possess will commonly be those established by the law, which in these circumstances can be said to control the economy. As I have said, in 'The Problem of Social Cost' I had no intention of making a contribution to legal scholarship. I referred to legal cases because they afforded examples of real situations as against the imaginary ones normally used by economists in their analysis. It was undoubtedly an economist who invented the widget. But in 'The Problem of Social Cost' I did something else. I pointed out that the judges in their opinions often seemed to show a better understanding of the economic problem than did many economists even though their views were not always expressed in a very explicit fashion. I did this not to praise the judges but to shame economists.[28]
Despite wandering accidentally into law and economics, the opportunity to edit the Journal of Law and Economics was instrumental in bringing him to the University of Chicago:
[W]hen I was approached to fill Aaron Director's place on his retirement, what I found most attractive about coming to Chicago was the opportunity it gave me of editing the Journal. Indeed, it is probable that without the Journal I would not have come to Chicago. I knew nothing of the original aim of the Journal. What I wanted to do was to encourage the type of research which I had advocated in 'The Problem of Social Cost', and I used my editorship of the Journal as a means of bringing this about.[28]
Coase believed that the University of Chicago was the intellectual center of law and economics. He concluded his Simons lecture by stating:
I am very much aware that, in concentrating in this lecture on law and economics at Chicago, I have neglected other significant contributions to the subject made elsewhere such as those by Guido Calabresi at Yale, by Donald Turner at Harvard, and by others. But it can hardly be denied that in the emergence of the subject of law and economics, Chicago has played a very significant part and one of which the University can be proud.[28]
Coase theorem
In law and economics, the Coase theorem (/ˈkoʊs/) describes the economic efficiency of an economic allocation or outcome in the presence of externalities. The theorem states that if trade in an externality is possible and there are sufficiently low transaction costs, bargaining will lead to a Pareto efficient outcome regardless of the initial allocation of property. In practice, obstacles to bargaining or poorly defined property rights can prevent Coasean bargaining. This 'theorem' is commonly attributed to Coase.
Coase conjecture
Another important contribution of Coase is the Coase conjecture, which is an informal argument that durable goods monopolists do not have market power because they are unable to commit to not lowering their prices in future periods.
Political views
When asked what he considered his politics to be, Coase stated,
I really don't know. I don't reject any policy without considering what its results are. If someone says there's going to be regulation, I don't say that regulation will be bad. Let's see. What we discover is that most regulation does produce, or has produced in recent times, a worse result. But I wouldn't like to say that all regulation would have this effect because one can think of circumstances in which it doesn't.[29]
Coase admitted that early in life, he aligned himself with socialism.
As a young man I was a Socialist. The first challenge to this belief came when, in 1931, 5 months before I took the final examinations for the B.Com. degree, I attended Arnold Plant's seminar at the London School of Economics (LSE). He introduced me to Adam Smith's invisible hand and to the advantages of a competitive system. He also pointed out that government schemes in the economic sphere were often ill-conceived and were introduced to placate special interests. I adopted many of Plant's positions but continued to regard myself as a Socialist. That this meant holding what could be considered, and were, inconsistent positions was not unusual at that time. Abba Lerner, a fellow student and a fine theorist, with whom I had a very friendly relation, also believed in the virtues of a competitive system but was even more attached to Socialism than I was.[27]
Guido Calabresi wrote that Coase's focus on transaction costs in The Nature of the Firm was the result of his socialist beliefs. Reflecting on this, Coase wrote: "It is very difficult to know where one's ideas come from but for all I know he may well be right." Coase continued:
My socialist sympathies gradually fell away and this process was accentuated as a result of being assigned in 1935 at LSE the course on the Economics of Public Utilities. I soon found out that very little was known about British public utilities and I set about making a series of historical studies on the water, gas, and electricity supply industries and of the Post Office and broadcasting.
These researches taught me much about the public utility industries and they certainly made me aware of the defects of government operation of these industries, whether municipal or through nationalisation. These researches were interrupted by the war, when I joined the civil service, at first, for a short period, in the Forestry Commission, then responsible for timber production, and for the rest of the war, in the Central Statistical Office, one of the offices of the War Cabinet. This war-time experience did not significantly influence my views but I could not help noticing that, with the country in mortal danger and despite the leadership of Winston Churchill, government departments often seemed more concerned to defend their own interests than those of the country.[27]
Ronald Coase Institute
Coase was research advisor to the Ronald Coase Institute, an organisation that promotes research on institutions and organizations – the laws, rules, customs, and norms – that govern real economic systems, with particular support for young scholars from developing and transitional countries.
Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics
The University of Chicago Law School carries on the legacy of Ronald Coase through the mission of the Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics. Each year, the University of Chicago Law School hosts the Coase Lecture, which was delivered in 2003 by Ronald Coase himself.[30]
Coase, Ronald; Wang, Ning (2011). "The Industrial Structure of Production: A Research Agenda for Innovation in an Entrepreneurial Economy". Entrepreneurship Research Journal. 2 (1). doi:10.2202/2157-5665.1026. S2CID154727631.
Mazda22015 Mazda2 (DJ) Genki hatchbackInformasiProdusenMazdaJuga disebutMazda DemioMasa produksi1996–presentBodi & rangkaKelasMobil subkompak (B)Tata letakMesin depan, Penggerak roda depanPlatformplatform Mazda DKronologiPendahuluMazda 121Autozam Revue Mazda2 merupakan kendaraan sedan yang diproduksi oleh perusahaan Jepang, Mazda sejak tahun 1996 hingga untuk pasaran global. Mazda2 pertama kali diluncurkan tahun 1996 dengan kendaraan 4 pintu. Mobil ini pertama kali hadir di Indones...
Commune in Auvergne-Rhône-Alpes, FranceChalanconCommuneLocation of Chalancon ChalanconShow map of FranceChalanconShow map of Auvergne-Rhône-AlpesCoordinates: 44°30′37″N 5°20′54″E / 44.5103°N 5.3483°E / 44.5103; 5.3483CountryFranceRegionAuvergne-Rhône-AlpesDepartmentDrômeArrondissementDieCantonLe DioisIntercommunalityDioisGovernment • Mayor (2020–2026) Isabelle Plasse[1]Area136 km2 (14 sq mi)Population (2021...
Italian footballer and manager Guido Moda Guido ModaPersonal informationFull name Guido ModaDate of birth (1885-07-11)11 July 1885Place of birth Piavon di Oderzo, ItalyDate of death 5 November 1957(1957-11-05) (aged 72)Place of death Bergamo, ItalyPosition(s) DefenderSenior career*Years Team Apps (Gls)1903–1908 Milan 11 (0)1908–1909 Kadıköy 1909–1912 Milan 16 (0)Managerial career1919–1921 Milan1926 Milan *Club domestic league appearances and goals Guido Moda (11 July 1885 – 5...
SD Negeri Tugu 10InformasiDidirikan03 Desember 1986JenisNegeriAkreditasiANomor Statistik Sekolah101020225035Nomor Pokok Sekolah Nasional20228979Kepala SekolahYusti S.PdRentang kelasI, II, III, IV, V, VIKurikulumKurikulum 2013StatusSekolah Standar NasionalAlamatLokasiJalan Taman Duta II №6, Tugu, Kec. Cimanggis, Depok, Jawa Barat, IndonesiaTel./Faks.(021) 825378Situs webSitus [email protected] SD Negeri Tugu 10 adalah sebuah sekolah dasar negeri yang terletak di ...
باراك أوباما يؤدي اليمين الدستورية كرئيس الولايات المتحدة ويده على الكتاب المقدس لابراهام لنكولن كانت هناك ادعاءات بأن باراك أوباما مسلمٌ سرًا، أو أنه المسيح الدجال بحسب علم الآخرات المسيحية (الإسخاتولوجيا المسيحية)، اقتُرح ذلك منذ حملته الانتخابية لمجلس الشيوخ الأمريك...
Type of algebraic integer In mathematics, a Pisot–Vijayaraghavan number, also called simply a Pisot number or a PV number, is a real algebraic integer greater than 1, all of whose Galois conjugates are less than 1 in absolute value. These numbers were discovered by Axel Thue in 1912 and rediscovered by G. H. Hardy in 1919 within the context of Diophantine approximation. They became widely known after the publication of Charles Pisot's dissertation in 1938. They also occur in the uniqueness...
A Highland mercenary fighting in Europe during the Thirty Years War, with a bow, plaid and blue bonnet. Redshank was a nickname for Scottish mercenaries from the Highlands and Western Isles contracted to fight in Ireland; they were a prominent feature of Irish armies throughout the 16th century. They were called redshanks because they went dressed in plaids and waded bare-legged through rivers in the coldest weather. An alternative etymology, illustrated by Jamieson by a quote from Sir Walter...
Artikel ini bukan mengenai Kisi heksagonal. Sistem kristal Trigonal Heksagonal Sistem kisi Rombohedral Heksagonal Contoh Dolomit (putih) α-Kuarsa Beril Dalam kristalografi, keluarga kristal heksagonal adalah salah satu dari 7 keluarga kristal, yang mencakup dua sistem kristal (heksagonal dan trigonal) dan dua sistem kisi (heksagonal dan rombohedral). Meskipun sering disalahartikan, sistem kristal trigonal dan sistem kisi rombohedral tidaklah setara (lihat bagian sistem kristal di bawah).[...
Typically Catholic shrines This article may contain unverified or indiscriminate information in embedded lists. Please help clean up the lists by removing items or incorporating them into the text of the article. (July 2016) Façade of the Basilica di Santa Maria Maggiore in Rome, Italy Part of a series on theMariologyof the Catholic ChurchImmaculate Conception by Bartolomé Esteban Murillo (c. 1675) Overview Prayers Antiphons Titles Hymns to Mary Devotional practices Saints Societies C...
Series of peace treaties signed in late 1697 Peace of RyswickTreaty of Peace between France and SpainTreaty of Peace between France and EnglandSuspension of Armed Conflict in Germany between France and the Holy Roman EmpireTreaty of Peace and Commerce between France and the Dutch RepublicSeparate Article for the Dutch RepublicTreaty of Peace between France and the Holy Roman EmpireHuis ter Nieuwburg, location for the negotiationsContextEnd of the 1689–1697 Nine Years War; King William's War...
Bank Nasional CekoČeská národní banka (dalam bahasa tidak diketahui)Logo Bank Nasional CekoKantor pusatPrague, Republik CekoKoordinat50°05′13″N 14°25′42″E / 50.08694°N 14.42833°E / 50.08694; 14.42833Didirikan1 Januari 1993(1919 sebagai Kantor Perbankan Kementerian Keuangan)Pemilik100% kepemilikan negara[1]GubernurAleš MichlNegaraRepublik CekoMata uangKoruna CekoCZK (ISO 4217)Cadangan62 630 juta USD[1]PendahuluBank Negara ...
In Uzbekistan l'omosessualità maschile è illegale ed è punita con una multa o una pena detentiva fino a 3 anni a differenza di quella femminile che è legale.[1] Leggi relative all'omosessualità Le persone LGBT non dispongono di alcuna tutela all'interno del paese e non esiste alcun riconoscimento legale per le coppie formate da persone dello stesso sesso. Tabella riassuntiva Depenalizzazione dell'omosessualità maschile (punita fino a 3 anni di carcere) / femminile Uguale età de...
روبين بينيا معلومات شخصية الاسم الكامل روبين بينيا خيمينيز الميلاد 18 يوليو 1991 (العمر 32 سنة)آبلة ، إسبانيا الطول 1.70 م (5 قدم 7 بوصة) مركز اللعب جناح أيمن الجنسية إسباني معلومات النادي النادي الحالي أوساسونا الرقم 15 مسيرة الشباب سنوات فريق ريال أبيلا للشباب المسير�...
When a Feller Needs a FriendPoster rilis teatrikalSutradaraHarry A. PollardProduserHarry A. PollardSkenarioFrank ButlerSylvia ThalbergBerdasarkanLimpy, the Boy Who Felt Neglectedoleh William Andrew JohnstonPemeranJackie CooperCharles Chic SaleRalph GravesDorothy PetersonAndy ShufordHelen ParrishSinematograferHarold RossonPenyuntingWilliam LeVanwayPerusahaanproduksiCosmopolitan ProductionsDistributorMetro-Goldwyn-MayerTanggal rilis 30 April 1932 (1932-04-30) Durasi74 menitNegaraAmerika Se...
United States Army general This article relies largely or entirely on a single source. Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page. Please help improve this article by introducing citations to additional sources.Find sources: John Bradbury Bennet – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (August 2019) John Bradbury BennetJohn Bradbury BennetBorn(1865-12-06)December 6, 1865New Brunswick, New JerseyDiedSeptember 2, 1930(1930-09-02) (aged 6...
Questa voce sugli argomenti calciatori francesi e calciatori marocchini è solo un abbozzo. Contribuisci a migliorarla secondo le convenzioni di Wikipedia. Segui i suggerimenti dei progetti di riferimento 1, 2. Bilal BariNazionalità Marocco Altezza184 cm Calcio RuoloAttaccante Squadra svincolato CarrieraGiovanili 2005-2008 Montigny-en-Gohelle2008-2018 Lens Squadre di club1 2015-2018 Lens 257 (16)2018 Lens1 (0)2018-2019→ RS Berkane10 (1)2019-2020 Concord...