Profit (economics)

Difference between how accountants and economists view a firm

In economics, profit is the difference between revenue that an economic entity has received from its outputs and total costs of its inputs, also known as surplus value.[1] It is equal to total revenue minus total cost, including both explicit and implicit costs.[2]

It is different from accounting profit, which only relates to the explicit costs that appear on a firm's financial statements. An accountant measures the firm's accounting profit as the firm's total revenue minus only the firm's explicit costs. An economist includes all costs, both explicit and implicit costs, when analyzing a firm. Therefore, economic profit is smaller than accounting profit.[3]

Normal profit is often viewed in conjunction with economic profit. Normal profits in business refer to a situation where a company generates revenue that is equal to the total costs incurred in its operation, thus allowing it to remain operational in a competitive industry. It is the minimum profit level that a company can achieve to justify its continued operation in the market where there is competition. In order to determine if a company has achieved normal profit, they first have to calculate their economic profit. If the company's total revenue is equal to its total costs, then its economic profit is equal to zero and the company is in a state of normal profit. Normal profit occurs when resources are being used in the most efficient way at the highest and best use. Normal profit and economic profit are economic considerations while accounting profit refers to the profit a company reports on its financial statements each period.

Normal profit = Total revenue – Total costs
Normal profit = Revenues – Total costs
Normal profit = Revenues – (Implicit costs + Explicit costs)

Economic profits arise in markets which are non-competitive and have significant barriers to entry, i.e. monopolies and oligopolies. The inefficiencies and lack of competition in these markets foster an environment where firms can set prices or quantities instead of being price-takers, which is what occurs in a perfectly competitive market.[4] In a perfectly competitive market when long-run economic equilibrium is reached, economic profit would become non-existent, because there is no incentive for firms either to enter or to leave the industry.[5]

Competitive and contestable markets

Only in the short run can a firm in a perfectly competitive market make an economic profit.

Companies do not make any economic profits in a perfectly competitive market once it has reached a long run equilibrium. If an economic profit was available, there would be an incentive for new firms to enter the industry, aided by a lack of barriers to entry, until it no longer existed.[6] When new firms enter the market, the overall supply increases. Furthermore, these intruders are forced to offer their product at a lower price to entice consumers to buy the additional supply they have created and to compete with the incumbent firms (see Monopoly profit § Persistence).[7][8][9][10] As the incumbent firms within the industry face losing their existing customers to the new entrants,[11] they are also forced to reduce their prices. Therefore, increased competition reduces price and cost to the minimum of the long run average costs. At this point, price equals both the marginal cost and the average total cost for each good production.[7][8] Once this has occurred a perfect competition exists and economic profit is no longer available.[12] When this occurs, economic agents outside the industry find no advantage to entering the market, as there is no economic profit to be gained. Then, the supply of the product stops increasing, and the price charged for the product stabilizes, settling into an equilibrium.[7][8][9]

The same is likewise true of the long run equilibria of monopolistically competitive industries, and more generally any market which is held to be contestable. Normally, a firm that introduces a differentiated product can initially secure temporary market power for a short while (See Monopoly Profit § Persistence). At this stage, the initial price the consumer must pay for the product is high, and the demand for, as well as the availability of the product in the market, will be limited. In the long run however, when the profitability of the product is well established, and because there are few barriers to entry,[7][8][9] the number of firms that produce this product will increase. Eventually, the supply of the product will become relatively large, and the price of the product will reduce to the level of the average cost of production. When this finally occurs, all economic profit associated with producing and selling the product disappears, and the initial monopoly turns into a competitive industry.[7][8][9] In the case of contestable markets, the cycle is often ended with the departure of the former "hit and run" entrants to the market, returning the industry to its previous state, just with a lower price and no economic profit for the incumbent firms.

Economic profit can, however, occur in competitive and contestable markets in the short run, since short run economic profits attract new competitors and prices fall. Economic loss forces firms out of the industry and prices rise till marginal revenue equals marginal cost, then reach long run equilibrium. As a result of firms jostling for market position. Once risk is accounted for, long-lasting economic profit in a competitive market is thus viewed as the result of constant cost-cutting and performance improvement ahead of industry competitors, allowing costs to be below the market-set price.

Uncompetitive markets

A monopolist can set a price in excess of costs, making an economic profit (shaded). The above picture shows a monopolist (only one firm in the industry/market) that obtains a (monopoly) economic profit. An oligopoly usually has "economic profit" also, but usually faces an industry/market with more than just one firm (they must share available demand at the market price).

Economic profit is much more prevalent in uncompetitive markets such as in a perfect monopoly or oligopoly situation, where few substitutes exit. In these scenarios, individual firms have some element of market power. Although monopolists are constrained by consumer demand, they are not price takers, but instead either price or quantity setters. Due to the output effect and the price effect, marginal revenue for uncompetitive markets is very different from marginal revenue for competitive firms.[13] In the output effect, more output is sold, quantity sold is higher. In the price effect, this reduces the prices firms charge for every unit they sell, and cut in price reduces revenue on the units it was already selling. Therefore, in uncompetitive market, marginal revenue is less than its price. This allows the firm to set a price which is higher than that which would be found in a similar but more competitive industry, allowing the firms to maintain an economic profit in both the short and long run.[7][8]

The existence of economic profits depends on the prevalence of barriers to entry, which stop other firms from entering into the industry and sapping away profits like they would in a more competitive market.[10] Examples of barriers to entry include patents, land rights, and certain zoning laws.[14] These barriers allow firms to maintain a large portion of market share due to new entrants being unable to obtain the necessary requirements or pay the initial costs of entry.

An oligopoly is a case where barriers are present, but more than one firm is able to maintain the majority of the market share. In an oligopoly, firms are able to collude and limit production, thereby restricting supply and maintaining a constant economic profit.[7][10][2] An extreme case of an uncompetitive market is a monopoly, where only one firm has the ability to supply a good which has no close substitutes.[14] In this case, the monopolist can set its price at any level it desires, maintaining a substantial economic profit. In both scenarios, firms are able to maintain an economic profit by setting prices well above the costs of production, receiving an income that is significantly more than its implicit and explicit costs.

Government intervention

The existence of uncompetitive markets puts consumers at risk of paying substantially higher prices for lower quality products.[15] When monopolies and oligopolies hold large portions of the market share, less emphasis is placed on consumer demand than there would be in a perfectly competitive market, especially if the good provided has an inelastic demand. Government intervention in the form of restrictions and subsidies can also create uncompetitive markets.[16] Governments can also intervene in uncompetitive markets in an attempt to raise the number of firms in the industry, but these firms cannot support the needs of consumers as if they were born out of a profit generated on a competitive market basis.[17] [neutrality is disputed]

In a regulated industry, the government examines firms' marginal cost structure and allows them to charge a price that is no greater than this marginal cost. This does not necessarily ensure zero economic profit for the firm, but eliminates a monopoly profit.

Competition laws were created to prevent powerful firms from using their economic power to artificially create barriers to entry in an attempt to protect their economic profits.[8][9][10] This includes the use of predatory pricing toward smaller competitors.[7][10][2] For example, in the United States, Microsoft Corporation was initially convicted of breaking Anti-Trust Law and engaging in anti-competitive behaviour in order to form one such barrier in United States v. Microsoft. After a successful appeal on technical grounds, Microsoft agreed to a settlement with the Department of Justice in which they were faced with stringent oversight procedures and explicit requirements[18] designed to prevent this predatory behaviour. With lower barriers, new firms can enter into the market again, making the long run equilibrium much more like that of a competitive industry, with no economic profit for firms and more reasonable prices for consumers.

On the other hand, if a government feels it is impractical to have a competitive market—such as in the case of a natural monopoly—it will allow a monopolistic market to occur. The government will regulate the existing uncompetitive market and control the price the firms charge for their product.[8][9] For example, the old AT&T (regulated) monopoly, which existed before the courts ordered its breakup, had to get government approval to raise its prices. The government examined the monopoly's costs, and determined whether or not the monopoly should be able raise its price. If the government felt that the cost did not justify a higher price, it rejected the monopoly's application for a higher price. Though a regulated firm will not have an economic profit as large as it would in an unregulated situation, it can still make profits well above a competitive firm in a truly competitive market.[9]

Maximization

It is a standard economic assumption (although not necessarily a perfect one in the real world) that, other things being equal, a firm will attempt to maximize its profits.[19] Given that profit is defined as the difference in total revenue and total cost, a firm achieves its maximum profit by operating at the point where the difference between the two is at its greatest. The goal of maximizing profit is also what leads firms to enter markets where economic profit exists, with the main focus being to maximize production without significantly increasing its marginal cost per good. In markets which do not show interdependence, this point can either be found by looking at these two curves directly, or by finding and selecting the best of the points where the gradients of the two curves (marginal revenue and marginal cost respectively) are equal.[14] In the real world, it is not so easy to know exactly firm's marginal revenue and the marginal cost of last goods sold. For example, it is difficult for firms to know the price elasticity of demand for their good – which determines the MR.[20] In interdependent markets, It means firm's profit also depends on how other firms react, game theory must be used to derive a profit maximizing solution.

Another significant factor for profit maximization is market fractionation. A company may sell goods in several regions or in several countries. Profit is maximized by treating each location as a separate market.[21] Rather than matching supply and demand for the entire company the matching is done within each market. Each market has different competitions, different supply constraints (like shipping) and different social factors. When the price of goods in each market area is set by each market then overall profit is maximized.

Other applications of the term

The social profit from a firm's activities is the accounting profit plus or minus any externalities or consumer surpluses that occur in its activity. An externality including positive externality and negative externality is an effect that production/consumption of a specific good exerts on people who are not involved.[7][10][2] Pollution is an example for negative externality.

Consumer surplus is an economic indicator which measures consumer benefits.[7][10][2] The price that consumers pay for a product is not greater than the price they desire to pay, and in this case there will be consumer surplus.

For the supply side of economics, the general school of thought is that profit is meant to ensure shareholder yield. While it is the case that profits are a means for shareholder returns, it also fulfills other functions. A target surplus may secure long-term solvency in the event of facing potential adversity. Capital surplus may be used to finance investments with significant capital expenditures or charitable contributions. All in all, producer surplus concerns several factors of interest for a for-profit economic entity.[22][23]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Arnold, Roger A. (2001). Economics (5 ed.). South-Western College Publishing. p. 475. ISBN 9780324071450. Retrieved 14 April 2021. Economic profit is the difference between total revenue and total opportunity cost, including both its explicit and implicit components. [...] Economic profit = Total revenue – Total opportunity cost [...]
  2. ^ a b c d e Black, 2003.
  3. ^ Mankiw, Gregory (2013). Principles of Economics. CENGAGE Lesrning.
  4. ^ Hubbard, Glenn; O'Brien, Anthony (2014). Essentials of Economics, Global Edition (4 ed.). Pearson Education Limited. p. 397. ISBN 9781292079172.
  5. ^ Lipsey, 1975. pp. 285–59.
  6. ^ Lipsey, 1975. p. 217.
  7. ^ a b c d e f g h i j Chiller, 1991.
  8. ^ a b c d e f g h Mansfield, 1979.
  9. ^ a b c d e f g LeRoy Miller, 1982.
  10. ^ a b c d e f g Tirole, 1988.
  11. ^ Saloner, Garth (2001). Strategic Management. John Wiley. p. 216.
  12. ^ Desai, Meghnad (16 March 2017). "Profit and Profit Theory" (PDF). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 2. pp. 1–14. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1319-2. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  13. ^ Mankiw, Gregory (2016). principles of economics. Cengage learning. p. 288.
  14. ^ a b c Perloff, Jeffrey (2018). Microeconomics, Global Edition (8 ed.). Harlow, United Kingdom: Pearson Education Limited. pp. 252–272. ISBN 9781292215624.
  15. ^ Pindyck, Robert; Rubinfeld, Daniel (2015). Microeconomics, Global Edition. Pearson Education Limited. p. 365. ISBN 9781292081977.
  16. ^ Winters, L.Alan (1987). "THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF AGRICULTURAL SUPPORT - A SURVEY". OECD Economic Studies. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.412.1477.
  17. ^ Rowe, James L. (2017). "Back to Basics: Economic concepts explained" (PDF). International Monetary Fund.
  18. ^ "United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Microsoft Corporation, Defendant", Final Judgement, Civil Action No. 98-1232, 12 November 2002.
  19. ^ Hirshleifer et al., 2005. p. 160.
  20. ^ Pettinger, Tejvan (16 July 2019). "Profit Maximisation". Economics help.
  21. ^ Regional Outlook (20 May 2021). "Industry Analysis Report and Forecast, 2021 - 2027". GLOBE NEWSWIRE.
  22. ^ "'Profit' variability in for-profit and not-for-profit hospitals". Science Direct. Retrieved 2 April 2023.
  23. ^ Duménil, Gérard; Lévy, Dominique (1993). "The Economics Of The Profit Rate". Books. Ideas. Retrieved 2 April 2023.

References

Read other articles:

العلاقات المارشالية الدومينيكية جزر مارشال دومينيكا   جزر مارشال   دومينيكا تعديل مصدري - تعديل   العلاقات المارشالية الدومينيكية هي العلاقات الثنائية التي تجمع بين جزر مارشال ودومينيكا.[1][2][3][4][5] مقارنة بين البلدين هذه مقارنة عامة ومرجع�...

 

 

Bandar Udara Ayers RockBandar Udara ConnellanBandar Udara Ayers Rock/ConnellanIATA: AYQICAO: YAYEInformasiJenisPublicPengelolaVoyages Indigenous Tourism Australia Pty LtdLokasiUluruKetinggian dpl mdplKoordinat25°11′10″S 130°58′32″E / 25.18611°S 130.97556°E / -25.18611; 130.97556Koordinat: 25°11′10″S 130°58′32″E / 25.18611°S 130.97556°E / -25.18611; 130.97556PetaYAYELocation in the Northern TerritoryLandasan pacu...

 

 

فيربورت   الإحداثيات 43°05′58″N 77°26′35″W / 43.099444444444°N 77.443055555556°W / 43.099444444444; -77.443055555556   [1] تاريخ التأسيس 1867  تقسيم إداري  البلد الولايات المتحدة[2][3]  التقسيم الأعلى بيرينتون  خصائص جغرافية  المساحة 1.6 ميل مربع  ارتفاع 474 قدم  عدد ال�...

Part of a series onBritish law Acts of Parliament of the United Kingdom Year      1801 1802 1803 1804 1805 1806 1807 1808 1809 1810 1811 1812 1813 1814 1815 1816 1817 1818 1819 1820 1821 1822 1823 1824 1825 1826 1827 1828 1829 1830 1831 1832 1833 1834 1835 1836 1837 1838 1839 1840 1841 1842 1843 1844 1845 1846 1847 1848 1849 1850 1851 1852 1853 1854 1855 1856 1857 1858 1859 1860 1861 1862 1863 1864 1865 1866 1867 1868 1869 1870 1871 1872 1873 1874 1875 1876 1877 1878 ...

 

 

Permainan rol hoki Rol hoki atau hoki sepatu roda adalah olahraga beregu yang menikmati popularitas yang signifikan di sejumlah negara Latin, dan di Eropa adalah olahraga yang dipraktikkan secara khusus di Portugal, Spanyol (terutama Catalonia dan Galisia) dan Italia (menjadi sangat populer di wilayah Veneto). Dua tim beranggotakan lima orang (empat skater dan satu penjaga gawang) mencoba mengarahkan bola dengan tongkat mereka ke gawang lawan. Bola hanya dapat digerakkan dengan tongkat, bukan...

 

 

Village in Fars province, Iran Village in Fars, IranQatar Boneh Persian: قطاربنهVillageQatar BonehCoordinates: 28°59′59″N 54°49′07″E / 28.99972°N 54.81861°E / 28.99972; 54.81861[1]Country IranProvinceFarsCountyNeyrizDistrictQatruyehRural DistrictQatruyehPopulation (2016)[2] • Total271Time zoneUTC+3:30 (IRST) Qatar Boneh (Persian: قطاربنه, also Romanized as Qaţār Boneh)[3] is a village in Qatruyeh...

New York City Subway service For the former Brooklyn–Manhattan Transit Corporation 3 service, see T (New York City Subway service). New York City Subway serviceSeventh Avenue ExpressA New Lots Avenue bound 3 train of R62s entering Van Siclen AvenueNorthern endHarlem–148th StreetSouthern endNew Lots Avenue (daytime)Times Square–42nd Street (late nights)Stations349 (late night service)Rolling stockR62[1][2](Rolling stock assignments subject to change)DepotLi...

 

 

Sporting event delegationSolomon Islands at the2015 World Championships in AthleticsWA codeSOLin BeijingCompetitors1Medals Gold 0 Silver 0 Bronze 0 Total 0 World Championships in Athletics appearances19831987–1993199519971999200120032005200720092011201320152017201920222023← 2013 2017 → Solomon Islands competed at the 2015 World Championships in Athletics in Beijing, China, from 22–30 August 2015. Results (q – qualified, NM – no mark, SB – season best) Men Track and road ...

 

 

Ugandan commercial bank I&M Bank UgandaCompany typeSubsidiary of I&M Holdings LimitedIndustryFinancial servicesFounded1993; 31 years ago (1993)HeadquartersKampala, UgandaKey peopleSuleiman I. Kiggundu Jr.Chairman Robin BairstowManaging Director & CEO[1]Sam NtulumeExecutive Director[2]ProductsBankingRevenueAftertax:USh 5.618 billion (US$1,520,400) (2022)[3]Total assetsUSh 786.5 billion (US$212.87 million) (2022)[...

Cet article est une ébauche concernant le Trentin-Haut-Adige. Vous pouvez partager vos connaissances en l’améliorant (comment ?) selon les recommandations des projets correspondants. Borgo d'Anaunia Administration Pays Italie Code postal 38013 Préfixe tel. 0463 Démographie Population 2 511 hab. (1er janvier 2023[1]) Densité 40 hab./km2 Géographie Coordonnées 46° 26′ 20″ nord, 11° 08′ 14″ est Superficie 6 323 h...

 

 

For folklore more generally, see Japanese folklore. For mythical folk-ballad of the Ainu, see yukar. The article's lead section may need to be rewritten. Please help improve the lead and read the lead layout guide. (December 2014) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Japanese folktales are an important cultural aspect of Japan. In commonplace usage, they signify a certain set of well-known classic tales, with a vague distinction of whether they fit the rigorous definition of ...

 

 

周處除三害The Pig, The Snake and The Pigeon正式版海報基本资料导演黃精甫监制李烈黃江豐動作指導洪昰顥编剧黃精甫主演阮經天袁富華陳以文王淨李李仁謝瓊煖配乐盧律銘林孝親林思妤保卜摄影王金城剪辑黃精甫林雍益制片商一種態度電影股份有限公司片长134分鐘产地 臺灣语言國語粵語台語上映及发行上映日期 2023年10月6日 (2023-10-06)(台灣) 2023年11月2日 (2023-11-02)(香�...

Canadian video game developer Rockstar Vancouver Inc.FormerlyBarking Dog Studios Ltd. (1998–2002)Company typeSubsidiaryIndustryVideo gamesFoundedMay 1998; 26 years ago (1998-05)FoundersGlenn BarnesPeter GrantMichael GyoriChristopher MairBrian ThalkenSean ThompsonDefunct9 July 2012 (2012-07-09)FateMerged into Rockstar TorontoHeadquartersVancouver, CanadaNumber of employees35 (2012)ParentRockstar Games (2002–2012) Rockstar Vancouver Inc. (formerly ...

 

 

Batalyon Artileri Medan 11/Guntur GeniLambang Yonarmed 11/76 Tarik/GGDibentuk27 Juni 1962NegaraIndonesiaCabangArmedTipe unitSatuan Bantuan TempurPeranPasukan Artilleri DaratBagian dariResimen Armed 2/Putra YudhaMarkasMagelang, Jawa TengahJulukanYon Armed 11/76/GGYMotoVajra Ambrung NirbayaBaretHijauMaskotGuntur GeniUlang tahun27 JuniAlutsistaMeriam M-48 76mm Batalyon Artileri Medan 11/Guntur Geni atau Yon Armed 11/76/Tarik/Kostrad merupakan satuan pelaksana bantuan tempur di jajaran Resimen Ar...

 

 

Protocolo de mensajes de control de InternetFamilia Familia de protocolos de InternetFunción Control y notificación de errores del Protocolo de InternetPuertos 1Ubicación en la pila de protocolos Red ICMPIP Enlace Ethernet, Token Ring,FDDI, ... Estándares RFC 792 (1981)[editar datos en Wikidata] El protocolo de mensajes de control de Internet (en inglés: Internet Control Message Protocol y conocido por sus siglas ICMP) es parte del conjunto de protocolos IP. Es utilizado para e...

For other people named Mary of Burgundy, see Mary of Burgundy (disambiguation). Duchess consort of Savoy Mary of BurgundyDuchess consort of SavoyBorn1386Dijon, BurgundyDied1428 (aged 41–42)Chateau of Thonon les BainsSpouseAmadeus VIII of SavoyIssueMargaret of SavoyAnthony of SavoyAnthony of SavoyMargaret, Countess Palatine of the RhineMarie, Duchess of MilanAmadeus of Savoy, Prince of PiemonteLouis of SavoyBonne of SavoyPhilip of Savoy, Count of GenèveHouseHouse of Valois-Burgundy...

 

 

Dutch–American music corporation Universal Records redirects here. For Universal Records 1988–1989, see Universal Records (1988). For Universal Records 1995–2006, see Universal Records (1995−2006). For other uses, see Universal Records (disambiguation). For the Chicago recording studio, see Universal Recording Corporation. Universal Music Group N.V.Operational headquarters in Santa Monica, CaliforniaFormerlyDecca Records (USA business) (1934–1971)MCA Records (1971–1989)MCA Music E...

 

 

ديفيد بلاكويل   معلومات شخصية اسم الولادة (بالإنجليزية: David Harold Blackwell)‏[1]  الميلاد 24 أبريل 1919 [2]  سينتراليا  الوفاة 8 يوليو 2010 (91 سنة) [3][2]  بيركيلي[1]  سبب الوفاة سكتة دماغية[4]  مواطنة الولايات المتحدة  العرق عرق أسود[1]  عضو في...

العلاقات الباربادوسية التشادية باربادوس تشاد   باربادوس   تشاد تعديل مصدري - تعديل   العلاقات الباربادوسية التشادية هي العلاقات الثنائية التي تجمع بين باربادوس وتشاد.[1][2][3][4][5] مقارنة بين البلدين هذه مقارنة عامة ومرجعية للدولتين: وجه المق...

 

 

SafariScribe is currently experiencing significant stress that may affect their ability to work on Wikipedia. They may choose to work in quieter areas and avoid complicated tasks or areas prone to conflict. They may also respond to talk page or email messages more slowly than usual, and your patience is greatly appreciated. Thank you. Archives Index 1 January - February 2024 March 2024 April 2024 This page was last edited or modified by Gabriel601 (talk). 8 June 2024   News and notes: Wikime...