Organic composition of capital

The organic composition of capital (OCC) is a concept created by Karl Marx in his theory of capitalism, which was simultaneously his critique of the political economy of his time. It is derived from his more basic concepts of 'value composition of capital' and 'technical composition of capital'. Marx defines the organic composition of capital as "the value-composition of capital, in so far as it is determined by its technical composition and mirrors the changes of the latter".[1] The 'technical composition of capital' measures the relation between the elements of constant capital (plant, equipment and materials) and variable capital (wage workers). It is 'technical' because no valuation is here involved. In contrast, the 'value composition of capital' is the ratio between the value of the elements of constant capital involved in production and the value of the labor. Marx found that the special concept of 'organic composition of capital' was sometimes useful in analysis, since it assumes that the relative values of all the elements of capital are constant.

Overview

In Book I of Capital, Marx made the simplifying assumption that all valuation was in terms of what is often called labor-values (and he called 'values'). In Book III, however, he states that equilibrium values between industries could not be directly proportional to their labor content. The latter only determined equilibrium values in his pre-capitalist 'Simple Commodity Production', where the producers owned their means of production and natural resources were used freely. In Book III, first he assumed that land could be used freely and showed that the equilibrium prices were his 'prices of production'. Later, when he introduced land ownership and the rent on land, the equilibrium prices were to be 'modified production prices' that took the rent of land into account. The implication of this is that the valuation used for the 'value composition of capital' had to be accordingly modified, since the labor-values used throughout Book I was an expedient he used in order to not excessively complicate the communication of this theory. But Marx was not able to complete to his satisfaction Books II and III.

The various distinct concepts related to the composition of capital are often used in contemporary Marxian economics as a theoretical alternative to similar neo-classical concepts. The neoclassical concept most similar to the increasing organic composition of capital is capital deepening. Marx's concept of constant capital is the monetary value of the plant, equipment and materials that are tied up in the production process. And his concept of variable capital is the money value that is tied up in the payment of wages. The concept of OCC does not apply to all capital assets, only to those invested in production (i.e. it excludes assets that are in the 'sphere of consumption', such as homes).

In Capital Vol. 3 Marx demonstrates that the organic composition of capital decisively influences industrial profitability. According to Marx, the OCC expresses the specific form which the capitalist mode of production gives to the relationship between means of production and labor power, determining the productivity of labor and the creation of a surplus product. This relationship has both technical and social aspects, reflecting the fact that simultaneously consumable use values and commercial exchange-values are being produced.

Marx argues that a rising organic composition of capital is a necessary effect of capital accumulation and competition in the sphere of production, at least in the long term. This means that the share of constant capital in the total capital outlay increases, and that labor input per product unit declines.

In his discussion, Marx leaves out of account components of capital other than labour-power and means of production invested in, such as the faux frais of production (incidental expenses). The full importance of the OCC emerges in chapter 8 of the third volume of Das Kapital.[2]

Ratios

The value composition of capital (VCC) is usually expressed as a ratio of constant capital to variable capital, or . Other measures are also used in the Marxian literature. One is . This is the ratio of constant capital to newly produced value (roughly, what modern economists call "value added"), i.e., surplus-value + variable capital and close to the concept of a capital/output ratio. Less common is the measure used by Paul M. Sweezy, i.e., , the ratio of constant capital to the total capital invested.

The total capital tied up by a capitalist enterprise includes more than fixed assets, materials and wages/salaries; it also includes liquid funds, reserves and other financial assets. For instance, an employer must normally reserve funds to pay for ongoing operating expenses, until these are recouped from product sales.

Measures

An empirical proxy measure for the technical composition of capital (TCC) is the average amount of fixed equipment and materials used per worker (capital intensity), or the ratio of the average amount of equipment & materials used to the total hours worked. The value composition of capital (VCC) is usually measured by summing the value of fixed capital ("Cf") and intermediate expenditures (circulating capital or "Cc") and dividing the total by the value of labour costs (V). The estimation procedure is not simple, for example because compensation of employees includes more than wages and part of the tax levy constitutes an element of surplus value.

In modern national accounts, an empirical proxy of the flow of variable capital is the wage-payments associated with productive activity in an accounting period, and a proxy for constant capital (flow measure) is depreciation charges + intermediate consumption; a stock measure of constant capital would be the fixed capital stock plus the average value of inventories held during the period of account (usually a year). However, because the "circulating" component of constant capital (denoted "Cc") includes purchases of external services and other operating costs, the stock of Cc is sometimes measured as the flow of intermediate consumption divided by the average inventory level.

The variable capital actually tied up by an enterprise at any point in time will usually be less than the annual flow value, because wages can in part be paid out of revenues received from ongoing product sales. Thus, the capital reserves held by an enterprise for paying wages may, at any time, be only 1/10 or so of their annual flow value.

The most accurate quantitative estimates for the OCC refer to the outlays in specific sectors, e.g. manufacturing.

Examples

By any of these measures, the plant- and machinery-intensive oil industry would have a high organic composition of capital, while labor-intensive businesses such as catering would tend to have a low OCC. The OCC varies according to differences in production technology, between sectors of an economy, or according to changes in production technology over time.

The OCC and crises

The magnitude of the OCC is important in Marxist crisis theory because of its impact on the average rate of profit. The implication of a rise in the organic composition of capital is a declining rate of profit; for every new increase in surplus-value realised as profit from sales, an even larger corresponding increase in constant capital investment becomes necessary.

But this represents only a tendency, Marx argues, because the fall of the rate of profit can be offset by counteracting influences. The main ones include:

  • buying constant capital inputs at a lower cost.
  • an increase in the rate of exploitation and productivity of labour power (including the intensity of work).
  • a reduction of the turnover-time of constant capital inputs.
  • the reduction of salaries and labour costs paid.
  • a pool of abundant cheap labor, at home or abroad.
  • foreign trade which reduces constant capital-input costs.
  • technological innovations which reduce constant capital-input costs.
  • the specific distribution of surplus-value as profit, interest, rent, taxes and fees, and the division between distributed and undistributed components of the new value added.
  • market expansion (more sales, in less time).
  • monopolistic or oligopolistic pricing of outputs, or in some way artificially raising output prices.
  • reduction of the tax burden
  • criminal methods to reduce costs and increase sales and profits

Because numerous different factors can affect profitability, the overall effects of a rising OCC on average industrial profitability therefore really have to be evaluated empirically in a longer time-span, e.g. 20–25 years.

Insofar as the trajectory of capitalist development is, as Marx argues, ruled by the quest for extra surplus-value, the economic fate of the system can be summarised as an interaction between the tendency of the profit rate to decline, and the factors that counteract it: in other words, the permanent battle to reduce costs, increase sales and increase profits.

The hypothetical final result of the rising OCC would be full automation of the production process, in which case labour-costs would be near-zero. This is argued to herald the end of capitalism's functioning as both a profit generating economic system for capitalists, and as a social system, among other things because the capitalist system does not contain a means for distributing incomes other than that based on labour-effort, and full automation would negate the concept of exploitation.[3]

Marx and Ricardo

The different organic compositions of capital of different branches of industry raised a problem for the classical economic schema of David Ricardo and others, who could not reconcile their labor-cost theory of price with the existence of differences in the OCC between sectors. The latter imply different profit rates in different industries. Also, while market competition would establish a ruling price level for a type of output, different enterprises would use more or less labour to produce it. For these reasons, values produced and prices realised by different producers would quantitatively diverge.

Marx either solved this problem with his theory of prices of production and the tendency for profitability differentials to be levelled out through competition, or he failed to solve it, according to which side of the debate over the transformation problem one finds convincing.

Others see this "problem" (the development of a mathematical relationship between prices and labor-values) as a false one, rejecting the idea that Marx aimed to use his labor theory value to understand relative prices. Here the argument is that he aimed to reveal only the social nature or "deep structure" of capitalist society.

In a third interpretation, Marx aspired both to relate values and prices, and offer a social critique, because both of these were necessary to make his case truly convincing. Here, the separate concepts of product-values and product-prices are regarded as essential for a theory of market dynamics and capitalist competition; it is argued that price behaviour in aggregate cannot be understood or theorised about at all without reference to value-relations, explicitly or implicitly.

There has been a lengthy theoretical and statistical dispute among Marxian economists about whether the organic composition of capital really does tend to, or has to rise historically, as Marx predicted, or, to put it differently, whether in aggregate technological progress has a "labor-saving bias", and causes the average profit rate to decline.

One sort of question asked is, why capitalists would introduce new technology, if doing so would result specifically in a lower profit rate on capital invested? Marx's reply is essentially that:

  • when a successful new technology or product is first introduced on the market, the pioneering producers typically obtain an additional profit (or superprofit), but when the use of the innovation spreads and is more generally applied, profitability declines for all producers.
  • competition between capitalists forces the introduction of new technologies, whether they like it or not, since the productivity gains of competitors threaten to put them out of business, or reduce their market-shares.
  • while average profit rates on capital invested may decline as a result, profit margins (or profit volumes) will increase, because more output can be produced and sold in a given accounting period, using the new technologies (implying unit-costs for products made will decline).

The statistical and historical evidence about the Kondratiev waves of capitalist development from the 1830s onwards is certainly favourable to Marx's theory of the rising organic composition of capital.[4] It is difficult to find industries where the secular historical trend is one of an increase in the share of wages in the total capital outlay. Generally, the opposite is the case.

However, it has been argued that the value of physical capital is notoriously difficult to measure empirically in an accurate way; and statistical time-series for economic variables over long periods are also susceptible to errors and distortions. The owners of a business may not even know exactly what the physical assets they use are currently worth, or what their business is currently worth, as a going concern. That worth is hypothetical until such time as the business is sold and paid for. However, the modern trend in official accounting standards is certainly for assets to be valued more and more at their current market value, or current replacement cost, rather than at historic (original acquisition) cost.

In addition, during severe economic slumps, physical capital assets are subject to devaluation, lie idle or are destroyed, while workers become unemployed; the empirical effect is to reduce the organic composition of capital. Likewise, non-profitable war production can also lower the average OCC.

Finally, a technological revolution can also radically change the proportions between constant and variable capital, reducing the cost of constant capital, and lowering the OCC. In that case, operating costs are reduced in a short span of time, or cheaper alternatives substitute for the inputs traditionally used.

Much less discussed in the economic literature is the effect on the organic composition of capital of the growth of the services sector in the developed countries. For example, does the widespread use of computers in labour-intensive services lower the OCC?

See also

References

  1. ^ Capital Vol. 1, Chapter 25 ("The General law of Capitalist Accumulation").
  2. ^ "MECW File Not Found".
  3. ^ Wood, John Cunningham (1996). Karl Marx's Economics: Critical Assessments I and II. Routledge. p. 429. ISBN 978-0415087148.
  4. ^ Shaikh, Anwar (2016). Capitalism : competition, conflict, crises. Oxford. ISBN 978-0-19-939063-2. OCLC 918879028.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)

Karl Marx, "The General Law of Capitalist Accumulation". [1]

  • Anwar Shaikh, "Organic Composition of Capital" [2]
  • Anwar Shaikh and Ahmet Tonak, Measuring the Wealth of Nations. Cambridge University Press.
  • Angelo Reati, "The Rate of Profit and the Organic Composition of Capital in the Post-1945 Long Wave: The Case of British Industry from 1959 to 1981". Review [of the Fernand Braudel Centre], Volume IX, Number 4, Spring 1986.
  • Ramin Ramtin: Capitalism and Automation – Revolution in Technology and Capitalist Breakdown. Pluto Press, London, Concord Mass. 1991.
  • Angelo Reati, "The Rate of Profit and the Organic Composition of Capital in West German Industry from 1960 to 1981", Review of Radical Political Economics; 18(1/2), Spring/Summer 1986, pages 56–86.
  • Christian Girschner, Die Dienstleistungsgesellschaft. Zur Kritik einer fixen Idee. Kőln: PapyRossa Verlag, 2003.

Read other articles:

بيتر دينيس ساذرلاند Peter Denis Sutherland ساذرلاند في عام 2011 المدعي العام لأيرلندا (19) في المنصب30 يونيو 1981 – 9 مارس 1982   باتريك كونولي المفوض الأوروبي للمنافسة في المنصب7 يناير 1985 – 5 يناير 1989 فرانس أندرياسن [الإنجليزية] ليون بريتان [الإنجليزية] مدير عام الاتفاقية العامة للتعريفا...

  لمعانٍ أخرى، طالع كرم (توضيح). الكَرْم هي مزرعة واسعة تستخدم لزراعة العنب الذي يستخدم في بعض الأحيان لإنتاج النبيذ، عادة في أغلب الدول (ماعدا دول الشرق الأوسط والدول الإسلامية) تتم زراعة العنب في الكروم بشكل رئيسي لصنع النبيذ، ولكن يستخدم العنب المزروع أيضا كزبيب أو �...

Refuge de l'île Snow Hill La cabane en 1902. Coordonnées 64° 21′ 50″ sud, 56° 59′ 32″ ouest Pays Argentine Suède Création 1902 Géolocalisation sur la carte : Antarctique Refuge de l'île Snow Hill modifier  Le refuge de l'île Snow Hill ou cabane de Nordenskjöld est une cabane de bois construite en février 1902 par le corps principal de l'expédition antarctique suédoise commandée par Otto Nordenskjöld, qui utilise l'île Snow Hill c...

American record label Candid RecordsParent companyCadence RecordsFounded1960 (1960)FounderArchie BleyerGenreJazz, BluesCountry of originUnited StatesLocationNew York Candid Records was a jazz record label first established in New York City. Early Candid Records The CANDID jazz label was founded in New York City in 1960 as a subsidiary of Cadence Records, owned by Archie Bleyer. The jazz writer and civil rights activist Nat Hentoff[1][2] was the label's (A&R) director ...

American college basketball season 1996–97 Wisconsin Badgers men's basketballNCAA Tournament First RoundConferenceBig Ten ConferenceRecord18-10 (11-7 Big Ten)Head coachDick Bennett (2nd season)Assistant coaches Brad Soderberg Shawn Hood Brian Hecker Home arenaUW Field House(capacity: 11,500)Seasons← 1995–961997–98 → 1996–97 Big Ten Conference men's basketball standings vte Conf Overall Team W   L   PCT W   L   PCT Iowa 12 – 6 &...

I Never Loved You AnywayLagu oleh The Corrsdari album Talk on CornersSisi-BWhat I KnowDirilis22 Desember 1997 (Britania)FormatSingel CDDirekam20 Oktober 1995GenrePop rock, folk-rockDurasi3:53LabelAtlanticPenciptaThe Corrs, Carole Bayer SagerProduserDavid Foster I Never Loved You Anyway adalah singel The Corrs yang dirilis tahun 1997. Lagu ini pertama muncul di album keduanya, Talk on Corners. Daftar lagu I Never Loved You Anyway (edit) – 3:53 What I Know – 3:48 I Never Loved You Anyway (a...

日本ローカルの事柄については「1992年の日本」をご覧ください。 千年紀: 2千年紀世紀: 19世紀 - 20世紀 - 21世紀十年紀: 1970年代 1980年代 1990年代 2000年代 2010年代年: 1989年 1990年 1991年 1992年 1993年 1994年 1995年 1992年 1992年の話題 主権国家 - 周年 - 表彰‎ 指導者 国の指導者 - 宗教指導者 社会 政治 - 選挙 - 法 - 

Book by Caroline Graham For other uses, see Ghost in the machine (disambiguation). This article relies largely or entirely on a single source. Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page. Please help improve this article by introducing citations to additional sources.Find sources: A Ghost in the Machine – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (January 2021) A Ghost in the Machine First edition (UK)AuthorCaroline GrahamCountryUnited KingdomS...

Friedrich Karl von Hessen-Kassel Friedrich Karl von Hessen-Kassel (um 1918) Friedrich Karl Ludwig Konstantin Landgraf von Hessen (* 1. Mai 1868 auf Gut Panker (Holstein); † 28. Mai 1940 in Kassel) wurde am 9. Oktober 1918 zum König von Finnland gewählt, nahm die Wahl jedoch nicht an und verzichtete am 14. Dezember 1918 auf die finnische Krone.[1][2] Als Regentenname war Fredrik Kaarle (auf Schwedisch Fredrik Karl) vorgeschlagen worden. Der in einigen Quellen genannte ...

Lutung Budeng Status konservasi Rentan Klasifikasi ilmiah Kerajaan: Animalia Filum: Chordata Kelas: Mammalia Ordo: Primates Famili: Cercopithecidae Genus: Trachypithecus Spesies: T. auratus Nama binomial Trachypithecus auratus(É. Geoffroy, 1812) Sinonim Simia Maura Schreber, 1774: 107-108 (nom. suppress.) Cercopithecus auratus É. Geoffroy, 1812[1] (basionym) Semnopithecus Pyrrhus Horsfield, 1823. Presbytes cristata — Gray, 1843: 3. Pithecus pyrrhus sondaicus Robinson & Kl...

ماوريسيو بيليغرينو معلومات شخصية الميلاد 5 أكتوبر 1971 (العمر 52 سنة)[1] الطول 1.93 م (6 قدم 4 بوصة) مركز اللعب مدافع الجنسية الأرجنتين  معلومات النادي النادي الحالي فيليز سارسفيلد (مدرب) مسيرة الشباب سنوات فريق 1982–1987 CA Sarmiento 1987–1990 فيليز سارسفيلد المسيرة الاحترافية1 ...

The Compleat Adventurer is a 1983 role-playing game supplement for published by Bard Games. Contents The Compleat Adventurer is a collection of character classes intended to be used for fantasy roleplaying games.[1] The book presented variant classes for thieves and fighters, such as bounty hunters, buccaneers, spies, and witch-hunters.[2]: 186  Reception Craig Sheeley reviewed The Compleat Adventurer in Space Gamer No. 72.[1] Sheeley commented that The...

Formal operation in mathematical logic See also: Reification (fallacy) This article includes a list of general references, but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations. Please help to improve this article by introducing more precise citations. (June 2022) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Hypostatic abstraction in mathematical logic, also known as hypostasis or subjectal abstraction, is a formal operation that transforms a predicate into a relation; for example Ho...

Painting by Neo Rauch Reactionary SituationArtistNeo RauchYear2002MediumOil on canvasDimensions210 cm × 400 cm (83 in × 160 in)LocationPrivate collection Reactionary Situation (German: Reaktionäre Situation) is a 2002 painting by the German artist Neo Rauch. It depicts a rural landscape with poplars, a dilapidated manor house, a little girl, a man working the ground with a stick, a man praying on his knees before a floating windmill and a colourful...

У этого термина существуют и другие значения, см. Olympus (значения). Эту статью необходимо исправить в соответствии с правилом Википедии об оформлении статей. Пожалуйста, помогите улучшить эту статью. OLYMPUS Corporation Тип публичная компания Листинг на бирже TYO: 7733 Основание 1919 Рас�...

Railway station in Kushiro, Hokkaido, Japan This article relies largely or entirely on a single source. Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page. Please help improve this article by introducing citations to additional sources.Find sources: Musa Station Hokkaido – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (July 2023) Musa Station武佐駅General informationLocationKushiro, HokkaidoJapanOperated by Hokkaido Railway CompanyLine(s)■ Nemur...

Municipality in Karnali, NepalKhandachakra खाँडाचक्रMunicipalityKhandachakraLocation in NepalCoordinates: 29°09′00″N 81°37′00″E / 29.15°N 81.616667°E / 29.15; 81.616667Country   NepalProvinceKarnaliDistrictKalikotNo. of wards11Government • TypeMayor-council • MayorMr. Kamal Bahadur Shahi (CPN (US)) • Deputy mayorMr. Ganesh Bahadur Shahi (Communist Party of Nepal (Maoist Centre))Area �...

South Korean TV series or program Same Bed, Different Dreams 2: You Are My DestinyPosterGenreVarietyTalk showPresented byKim GuraSeo Jang-hoonKim SookCountry of originSouth KoreaOriginal languageKoreanNo. of episodes319(as of 42023)ProductionProducersSeo Hye-jinAhn Jae-chulCamera setupMultiple-camera setupRunning time80 minutesProduction companySM C&COriginal releaseNetworkSBS TVRelease10 July 2017 (2017-07-10) –present Same Bed, Different Dreams 2 - You Are My Destiny (K...

Bilateral relationsItaly-Portugal relations Italy Portugal Italy–Portugal relations are the current and historical relations between the Italian Republic and the Portuguese Republic. Both nations are members of the Council of Europe, European Union, NATO, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Union for the Mediterranean and the United Nations. History Wedding between King Luís I of Portugal and Maria Pia of Savoy in Lisbon; 1862. Italy and Portugal have a long history of ...

1967 autobiographical novel by Boris Pahor Necropolis AuthorBoris PahorOriginal titleNekropolaLanguageAs of 2013, it has been translated twice to English. It has also been translated into French, German, Catalan, Finnish, Italian, Serbian, Spanish, Dutch, Croatian, Portuguese, and Esperanto; original in Slovene.Genreautobiography, HolocaustPublished1967PublisherDalkey Archive PressPublished in English1995ISBN9781564786111 Necropolis (Slovene: Nekropola) is an autobiographical novel ...