Risk compensation is a theory which suggests that people typically adjust their behavior in response to perceived levels of risk, becoming more careful where they sense greater risk and less careful if they feel more protected.[2] Although usually small in comparison to the fundamental benefits of safety interventions, it may result in a lower net benefit than expected or even higher risks.[3][n 1]
By way of example, it has been observed that motorists drove closer to the vehicle in front when the vehicles were fitted with anti-lock brakes. There is also evidence that the risk compensation phenomenon could explain the failure of condom distribution programs to reverse HIV prevalence and that condoms may foster disinhibition, with people engaging in risky sex both with and without condoms.
By contrast, shared space is an urban street design method which consciously aims to increase the level of perceived risk and uncertainty, thereby slowing traffic and reducing the number and seriousness of injuries.
Overview
Risk compensation is related to the broader term behavioral adaptation which includes all behavior changes in response to safety measures, whether compensatory or not. However, since researchers are primarily interested in the compensatory or negative adaptive behavior the terms are sometimes used interchangeably.[n 2] The more recent version emerged from road safety research after it was claimed that many interventions failed to achieve the expected level of benefits but has since been investigated in many other fields.[n 3][n 4]
Peltzman effect
The reduction of predicted benefit from regulations that intend to increase safety is sometimes referred to as the Peltzman effect in recognition of Sam Peltzman, a professor of economics at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, who published "The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation" in the Journal of Political Economy in 1975 in which he controversially suggested that "offsets (due to risk compensation) are virtually complete, so that regulation has not decreased highway deaths".[4] Peltzman claimed to originate this theory in the 1970s but it was used to oppose the requirement of safety equipment on trains in the Nineteenth Century.[5]
A reanalysis of his original data found numerous errors and his model failed to predict fatality rates before regulation.[6] According to Peltzman, regulation was at best useless, at worst counterproductive.[7][n 5] Peltzman found that the level of risk compensation in response to highway safety regulations was complete in original study. But "Peltzman's theory does not predict the magnitude of risk compensatory behaviour." Substantial further empirical work has found that the effect exists in many contexts but generally offsets less than half of the direct effect.[n 6] In the U.S., motor vehicle fatalities per population declined by more than half from the beginning of regulation in the 1960s through 2012. Vehicle safety standards accounted for most of the reduction augmented by seat belt use laws, changes in the minimum drinking age, and reductions in teen driving.[8]
The Peltzman effect can also result in a redistributing effect where the consequences of risky behaviour are increasingly felt by innocent parties (see moral hazard). By way of example, if a risk-tolerant driver responds to driver-safety interventions, such as compulsory seat belts, crumple zones, antilock brakes, etc. by driving faster with less attention, then this can result in increases in injuries and deaths to pedestrians.[9]
Risk homeostasis
Risk homeostasis is a controversial hypothesis, initially proposed in 1982 by Gerald J. S. Wilde, a professor at Queen's University in Canada, which suggests that people maximise their benefit by comparing the expected costs and benefits of safer and riskier behaviour and which introduced the idea of the target level of risk.[n 7] He proposed four constituents to a person's calculations relating to risk:[n 8]
Expected benefits of risky behavior (e.g., gaining time by speeding, fighting boredom, increasing mobility)
Expected costs of risky behavior (e.g., speeding tickets, car repairs, insurance surcharges)
Expected benefits of safe behavior (e.g., insurance discounts for accident-free periods, enhancement of reputation of responsibility)
Expected costs of safe behavior (e.g., using an uncomfortable seat belt, being called a coward by one's peers, time loss)
Wilde noted that when Sweden changed fromdriving on the left to driving on the right in 1967, this was followed by a marked reduction in the traffic fatality rate for 18 months after which the trend returned to its previous values. He suggested that drivers had responded to increased perceived danger by taking more care, only to revert to previous habits as they became accustomed to the new regime.[n 9] A similar pattern was seen following Iceland's switch from left- to right-hand driving.
In a Munich study, part of a fleet of taxicabs were equipped with anti-lock brakes (ABS), while the remainder had conventional brake systems. In other respects, the two types of cars were identical. The crash rates, studied over three years, were a little higher for the cabs with ABS,[10] Wilde concluded that drivers of ABS-equipped cabs took more risks, assuming that ABS would take care of them; non-ABS drivers were said to drive more carefully since they could not rely on ABS in a dangerous situation.[citation needed]
The idea of risk homeostasis is disputed. One author claimed that it received "little support",[n 10] another suggested that it "commands about as much credence as the flat earth hypothesis",[n 11] a third noted that the proposal did create considerable media attention: "What set the debate alight, rather like petrol on flames, was the proposition in 1982 that road users did not just adapt to perceptions of changing risk through compensatory behaviors, but that the process was a homeostatic one, producing overall equilibrium in safety-related outcomes".[n 12] Others claimed that road fatality statistics, which have fallen considerably since the introduction of safety measures, do not support the theory.[11][12][13][14][15]
Preventive measures
To create preventive measures in order to make a certain activity safer, risk compensation and risk compensation behavior has to be mapped in order to evaluate whether the measures are effective. When measures create risk compensation this might nullify the made measures. Then the measures might not lead to less injuries or in worse cases enhance injuries.
[3]
Examples
Road transport
Anti-lock brakes
Anti-lock braking systems are designed to increase vehicle safety by allowing the vehicle to steer while braking.
A number of studies show that drivers of vehicles with ABS tend to drive faster, follow closer and brake later, accounting for the failure of ABS to result in any measurable improvement in road safety. The studies were performed in Canada, Denmark, and Germany.[16][17][18] A study led by Clifford Winston and Fred Mannering, a professor of civil engineering at the University of South Florida supports risk compensation, terming it the "offset hypothesis".[19][20] A study of crashes involving taxicabs in Munich of which half had been equipped with anti-lock brakes noted that crash rate was substantially the same for both types of cab, and concluded this was due to drivers of ABS-equipped cabs taking more risks.[21]
A 1994 research study of people who both wore and habitually did not wear seatbelts concluded that drivers were found to drive faster and less carefully when belted.[24]
Several important driving behaviors were observed on the road before and after the belt use law was enforced in Newfoundland, and in Nova Scotia during the same period without a law. Belt use increased from 16 percent to 77 percent in Newfoundland and remained virtually unchanged in Nova Scotia. Four driver behaviors (speed, stopping at intersections when the control light was amber, turning left in front of oncoming traffic, and gaps in following distance) were measured at various sites before and after the law. Changes in these behaviors in Newfoundland were similar to those in Nova Scotia, except that drivers in Newfoundland drove slower on expressways after the law, contrary to the risk compensation theory.[25]
In Britain in 1981 at a time when the government was considering the introduction of seat belt legislation, John Adams of University College London, suggested that there was no convincing evidence of a correlation between the seat-belt legislation and reduction of injuries and fatalities based on a comparison between states with and without seat belt laws. He also suggested that some injuries were displaced from car drivers to pedestrians and other road users.[26] The "Isles Report" echoed these concerns.[27] Adams subsequently argued that the reduction in fatalities that followed the introduction of legislation could not be attributed with confidence to seat-belt use due to the simultaneous introduction of breath testing for driving under the influence of alcohol.[28]
However, a 2007 study based on data from the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS) of the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration concluded that between 1985 and 2002 there were "significant reductions in fatality rates for occupants and motorcyclists after the implementation of belt use laws", and that "seatbelt use rate is significantly related to lower fatality rates for the total, pedestrian, and all non-occupant models even when controlling for the presence of other state traffic safety policies and a variety of demographic factors".[29] A comprehensive 2003 US study also did "not find any evidence that higher seat belt usage has a significant effect on driving behavior." Their results showed that "overall, mandatory seat belt laws unambiguously reduce traffic fatalities."[30]
Swedish change to driving on the right
In Sweden, following the change from driving on the left to driving on the right in 1967 there was a drop in crashes and fatalities, which was linked to the increased apparent risk. The number of motor insurance claims went down by 40 percent, returning to normal over the next six weeks.[31][32] Fatality levels took two years to return to normal.[33][n 13]
Speed limits
The control of traffic speeds using effectively enforced speed limits and other traffic calming methods plays an important role in the reduction of road traffic casualties;[34][35] speed limit changes alone without accompanying enforcement or traffic calming measures will not.[36]
A 1994 study conducted to test the risk homeostasis theory, using a driving simulator, found that increasing posted speed limits and a reduction of speeding fines had significantly increased driving speed but resulted in no change in the accident frequency. It also showed that increased accident cost caused large and significant reductions in accident frequency but no change in speed choice. The results suggest that regulation of specific risky behaviors such as speed choice may have little influence on accident rates.[37]
Shared space is an approach to the design of roads, where risk compensation is consciously used to increase the level of uncertainty for drivers and other road users by removing traditional demarcations between vehicletraffic by removing curbs, road surface markings, and traffic signs. The approach has been found to result in lower vehicle speeds and fewer road casualties.[38]
Bicycle helmets
Campaigns and legislation to encourage the wearing of cycle helmets have not been shown to reduce significant head injuries,[39] and "there is evidence to suggest that some cyclists ride less cautiously when helmeted because they feel more protected".[40] In one experimental study, adults accustomed to wearing helmets cycled more slowly without a helmet, but no difference in helmeted and unhelmeted cycling speed was found for cyclists who do not usually wear helmets.[41] A Spanish study of traffic accidents between 1990 and 1999 found no strong evidence of risk compensation in helmet wearers but concluded that "this possibility cannot be ruled out".[42]
Motorists may also alter their behavior toward helmeted cyclists. One study by Walker in England found that 2,500 vehicles passed a helmeted cyclist with measurably less clearance (8.5 cm) than that given to the same cyclist unhelmeted (out of an average total passing distance of 1.2 to 1.3 metres).[43][44] The significance of these differences has been re-analysed by Olivier,[45] who argued that the effect on safety was not significant since the passing distances were over 1 metre,[46] and again by Walker, who disagreed with Olivier's conclusion.[44]
In 1988, Rodgers re-analysed data which supposedly showed helmets to be effective and found both data errors and methodological weaknesses. He concluded that in fact the data showed "bicycle-related fatalities are positively and significantly associated with increased helmet use" and mentioned risk compensation as one possible explanation of this association.[47]
Infrastructure
Levees are structures which run parallel to rivers and are meant to offer protection from flooding. The perception of safety can lead to unsafe land development in the floodplain which is supposed to be protected by the levee. Consequently, when a flood does occur or the levee breaches, the effects of that disaster will be greater than if the levee had not been built.[48]
Sport
Martial arts
This principle is recognised in some martial arts, including karate, where it is suggested that wearing protective gloves might lead to harder strikes and punches, possibly resulting in more severe injuries.[49] It has also been suggested in historical European martial arts.[50]
Ski helmets
Recent studies indicate that skiers wearing helmets go faster on average than non-helmeted skiers,[51] and that overall risk index is higher in helmeted skiers than non-helmeted skiers.[52] Moreover, while helmets may help prevent minor head injuries, increased usage of helmets has not reduced the overall fatality rate.[53]
Other recent studies have concluded that helmet use is not associated with riskier behavior among skiers and snowboarders, and that helmet usage reduces the risk and severity of head injuries.[2][n 14][n 15][54]
Football helmets
Some researchers have found the counterintuitive result that wearing helmets in gridiron football actually increases the chance of injury, and thus they recommend players occasionally practice without helmets. When hard shells were first introduced, the number of head injuries increased because players had a false sense of security and made more dangerous tackles.
Skydiving
'Booth's rule #2', often attributed to skydiving pioneer Bill Booth, states, "the safer skydiving gear becomes, the more chances skydivers will take, in order to keep the fatality rate constant".[1][55] Even though skydiving equipment has made huge leaps forward in terms of reliability, including the introduction of safety devices such as AADs, the fatality rate has stayed roughly constant when adjusted for the increasing number of participants.[56][57] This can largely be attributed to an increase in the popularity of high performance canopies, which fly much faster than traditional parachutes.[n 16] A greater number of landing fatalities in recent years has been attributed to high speed maneuvers close to the ground.[n 17]
Safety equipment in children
Experimental studies have suggested that children who wear protective equipment are likely to take more risks.[58]
Health
Risky sexual behavior and HIV/AIDS
Evidence on risk compensation associated with HIV prevention interventions is mixed. Harvard researcher Edward C. Green argued that the risk compensation phenomenon could explain the failure of condom distribution programs to reverse HIV prevalence, providing a detailed explanations of his views in an op-ed article for The Washington Post[59] and an extended interview with the BBC.[60] A 2007 article in the Lancet suggested that "condoms seem to foster disinhibition, in which people engage in risky sex either with condoms or with the intention of using condoms".[61][62] Another report compared risk behaviour of men based on whether they were circumcised.[63]
A 2015 study showed that adolescents with safe-sex beliefs (adolescents who believe that sex with condoms is 100% safe) have an earlier sexual initiation.[64]
PrEP
While pre-exposure prophylaxis (PrEP) with anti-HIV drugs appears to be extremely successful in suppressing the spread of HIV infection, there is some evidence that the reduction in HIV risk has led to some people taking more sexual risks; specifically, reduced use of condoms in anal sex,[65] raising risks of spreading sexually transmitted diseases other than HIV.
Tullock's spike, a thought experiment by Gordon Tullock in reversing the risk compensation effect
Notes
^Vrolix (2006) "Behavioural adaptation generally does not eliminate the safety gains from programmes, but tends to reduce the size of the expected effects"
^Vrolix (2006) "A term, closely related to risk compensation, is 'behavioural adaptation'. Behavioural adaptation is a wider term referring to all behavioural changes triggered by a safety measure (OECD, 1997). Strictly spoken, this includes all positive and negative behavioural changes induced by road safety measures. Nevertheless, the emphasis is primarily put on the negative aspects of this phenomenon."
^Vrolix (2006) "Risk compensation is the term given to a theory which tries to understand the behaviour of people in potentially hazardous activities. In the context of the road user, risk compensation refers to the tendency of road users to compensate for changes in the road system that are perceived as improving safety by adapting behaviour. (Elvik and Vaa, 2004). So measures, designed to improve traffic safety, may bring along negative consequences in a way that individuals increase the riskiness of their driving behaviour because they feel safer (Dulisse, 1997)"
^Hedlund (2000) "The early risk compensation literature deals with road safety... Several recent studies examine risk compensation in response to both aggregate and specific consumer product and workplace safety regulations"
^Hedlund (2000) "This conclusion startled the road safety community and challenged the role of government in attempting to improve safety through regulation. In Peltzman's view, government regulation was useless and perhaps even counterproductive."
^Wilde (1998) "The level of risk at which the net benefit is expected to maximize is called the target level of risk in recognition of the realization that people do not try to minimize risk (which would be zero at zero mobility), but instead attempt to optimize it"
^Wilde (1998) "Besides macroeconomic influences, there are other factors that influence the level of accepted risk; these are of a cultural, social, or psychological kind. In general, the amount of risk that people are willing (in fact, prefer) to take can be said to depend on four utility factors and will be greater to the extent that factors..."
^Wilde (1998) "In the fall of 1967 Sweden changed over from left hand to right hand traffic. This was followed by a marked reduction in the traffic fatality rate. About a year and a half later, the accident rate returned to the trend before the changeover."
^Hedlund (2000) "The extreme views of risk homeostasis have attracted little support"
^O'Neill & Williams (1998) "Risk homeostasis is not a theory. It is a hypothesis that repeatedly has been refuted by empirical studies. As Evans has noted, it commands about as much credence as the flat earth hypothesis"
^Rudin-Brown & Jamson (2013, p. 28), 'Early Theories of Behavioural Adaptations' by Oliver Carsten: "What set the debate alight, rather like petrol on flames, was the proposition in 1982 that road users did not just adapt to perceptions of changing risk through compensatory behaviors, but that the process was a homeostatic one, producing overall equilibrium in safety-related outcomes"
^Rudin-Brown & Jamson (2013) "An example of risk overestimation in the short run is offered by the experience in Sweden when that country changed from left- to right-hand driving in the fall of 1967. This intervention led to a marked surge in perceived risk that exceeded the target level and thus was followed by a very cautious behavior that caused a major decrease in road fatalities. ...the accident rate returned to 'normal' within 2 years."
^Ruedl et al. (2010) "Helmet use is not associated with riskier behaviour on slopes. In addition, helmet use has to be recommended because helmet use reduces the risk of head injuries among skiers and snowboarders"
^Ruedl et al. (2010) "Safety helmets clearly decrease the risk and severity of head injuries in skiing and snowboarding and do not seem to increase the risk of neck injury, cervical spine injury, or risk compensation behavior"
^Lessons to be Learned (2013) "The biggest opportunity for improvement in safety remains the selection and operation of main parachutes."
^Lessons to be Learned (2013) "It appears that most of the incidents happened under small (the average reported size was 107 square feet), highly loaded canopies."
Vrolix, Klara (2006). Behavioral adaptation, risk compensation, risk homeostatis and moral hazard in traffic safety. Hasselt University (Report). hdl:1942/4002.
^ abMasson, Maxime; Lamoureux, Julie; de Guise, Elaine (October 2019). "Self-reported risk-taking and sensation-seeking behavior predict helmet wear amongst Canadian ski and snowboard instructors". Canadian Journal of Behavioural Science. 52 (2): 121–130. doi:10.1037/cbs0000153. S2CID210359660.
^ abVan Tiggelen, D (2008). "Effective prevention of sports injuries: a model integrating efficacy, efficiency, compliance and risk-taking behaviour". British Journal of Sports Medicine. 42 (8): 648–652. doi:10.1136/bjsm.2008.046441. PMID18400875. S2CID42945041.
^Robertson, Leon S. (1977). "A Critical Analysis of Peltzman's "The Effects of Automobile Safety Regulation"". Journal of Economic Issues. 11 (3): 587–600. doi:10.1080/00213624.1977.11503463.
^Pope, Adam T.; Tollison, Robert D. (2010). ""Rubbin' is racin": evidence of the Peltzman effect from NASCAR". Public Choice. 142 (3–4): 507–513. doi:10.1007/s11127-009-9548-2. S2CID153527032. "The Peltzman (1975) effect predicts that when automobile safety regulations are made mandatory, at least some of their benefits will be offset by changes in the behavior of drivers
^Trimpop, R.M. (1994). The Psychology of Risk Taking Behavior. Elsevier. p. 219. ISBN978-0-444-89961-3. Over a period of 36 months they observed part of a taxi fleet in Munich, Germany. Half of the observed vehicles were equipped with an anti-lock braking system (ABS)... The overall accident rate showed a slight increase for ABS taxis, but no significant differences between cars with the superior brake-system (ABS) versus cars without the system
^Evans, Leonard (March 1986). "Risk Homeostasis Theory and Traffic Accident Data". Risk Analysis. 6 (1): 81–94. Bibcode:1986RiskA...6...81E. doi:10.1111/j.1539-6924.1986.tb00196.x. PMID3602497. risk homeostasis theory should be rejected because there is no convincing evidence supporting it and much evidence refuting it
^Oppe, S (1991). "The development of traffic and traffic safety in six developed countries". Accident Analysis and Prevention. 23 (5): 401–412. doi:10.1016/0001-4575(91)90059-E. PMID1741895.
^Ameen, J. R. M.; Naji, J. A. (2001). "Causal models for road accident fatalities in Yemen". Accident Analysis and Prevention. 33 (4): 547–561. doi:10.1016/S0001-4575(00)00069-5. PMID11426685.
^Grant and Smiley, "Driver response to antilock brakes: a demonstration of behavioural adaptation" from Proceedings, Canadian Multidisciplinary Road Safety Conference VIII, June 14–16, Saskatchewan 1993.
^Sagberg, Fridulv; Fosser, Stein; Sætermo, Inger-Anne F. (1997). "An investigation of behavioural adaptation to airbags and antilock brakes among taxi drivers". Accident Analysis & Prevention. 29 (3): 293–302. doi:10.1016/S0001-4575(96)00083-8. PMID9183467.
^Aschenbrenner; Biehl (1994). "Improved safety through improved technical measures? empirical studies regarding risk compensation processes in relation to anti-lock braking systems". In Trimpop; Wilde (eds.). Challenges to Accident Prevention: The issue of risk compensation behaviour. Groningen, NL: Styx Publications.
^Janssen, W (1994). "Seat-belt wearing and driving behavior: An instrumented-vehicle study". Accident Analysis and Prevention. 26 (2): 249–261. doi:10.1016/0001-4575(94)90095-7. PMID8198694.
^Adams, John (1985). Risk and Freedom: The Record of Road Safety Regulation. Transport Publishing Projects. ISBN978-0-948537-05-9.[page needed]
^Flock, Elizabeth (17 February 2012). "Dagen H: The day Sweden switched sides of the road (photo)". Washington Post. On the day of the change, only 150 minor accidents were reported. Traffic accidents over the next few months went down. ... By 1969, however, accidents were back at normal levels
^"On September 4 there were 125 reported traffic accidents as opposed to 130-196 from the previous Mondays. No traffic fatalities were linked to the switch. In fact, fatalities dropped for two years, possibly because drivers were more vigilant after the switch." Sweden finally began driving on the right side of the road in 1967. The Examiner Sept 2, 2009
^World Report on Road Traffic Injury Prevention. World Health Organization, World Bank Group. 2004. ISBN978-92-4-156260-7. Retrieved 2010-04-13. In high-income countries, an established set of interventions have contributed to significant reductions in the incidence and impact of road traffic injuries. These include the enforcement of legislation to control speed and alcohol consumption, mandating the use of seat-belts and crash helmets, and the safer design and use of roads and vehicles.
^"Speed limits". Medway Council. Archived from the original on 2010-12-30. Contrary to popular belief, local speed limits should only be used if 85 out of 100 vehicles are already travelling at the speed it is wished to impose. Experience shows the speeds of these 85 vehicles are likely to influence the speeds of the other 15. This makes the speed limit largely self-enforcing and consequently makes for a manageable enforcement task
^Hamilton-Baillie, Ben (2008). "Towards shared space"(PDF). Urban Design International. 13 (2): 130–138. doi:10.1057/udi.2008.13. S2CID110538901. A recognition of 'risk compensation effect' prompts a fresh understanding of the adverse effects of measures such as traffic signals, signs, pedestrian guard rails and barriers on safety, and of their tendency to discourage informal physical activity. It may seem perverse to argue that well being can be improved through making spaces feel riskier, but that is the firm conclusion from both research, and from empirical studies
^"Cycle helmets: A summary of the evidence"(PDF). Cycling UK. November 2019. p. 19. there is evidence to suggest that some cyclists ride less cautiously when helmeted because they feel more protected:...
^Walker, Ian (2007). "Drivers overtaking bicyclists: Objective data on the effects of riding position, helmet use, vehicle type and apparent gender". Accident Analysis & Prevention. 39 (2): 417–425. doi:10.1016/j.aap.2006.08.010. PMID17064655.
^Rodgers, Gregory B (1988). "Reducing Bicycle Accidents: A Re-evaluation of the Impacts of the CPSC Bicycle Standard and Helmet Use". Journal of Products Liability. 11 (4): 307–317.
^Wauters, S; Van Tiggelen, D (2016). "Injury Profile of Longsword fencing in Historical European Martial Arts". Journal of Combat Sports and Martial Arts. 7 (2): 87–88. hdl:1854/LU-8599986.
^Shealy, JE; Ettlinger, CF; Johnson, RJ (2005). "How Fast Do Winter Sports Participants Travel on Alpine Slopes?". Journal of ASTM International. 2 (7): 12092. doi:10.1520/JAI12092. The average speed for helmet users of 45.8 km/h (28.4 mph) was significantly higher than those not using a helmet at 41.0 km/h (25.4 mph)
^Ružić, L; Tudor, A (2011). "Risk-taking Behavior in Skiing Among Helmet Wearers and Nonwearers". Wilderness & Environmental Medicine. 22 (4): 291–296. doi:10.1016/j.wem.2011.09.001. PMID22137861. The main findings of this study indicate that the overall Risk Index is higher in helmeted skiers than non-helmeted skiers. The population that contributes the most to the overall Risk Index value is male helmet wearers, signifying that male helmet wearers take more risks while skiing than others
^Shealy, Jasper E.; et al. (2008). "Do Helmets Reduce Fatalities or Merely Alter the Patterns of Death?". Journal of ASTM International. 5 (10): 101504. doi:10.1520/JAI101504. This paper presents results that suggest that while helmets may be effective at preventing minor injuries, they have not been shown to reduce the overall incidence of fatality in skiing and snowboarding even though as many as 40% of the population at risk are currently using helmets
^Johansson, Frans (2012). The Click Moment: Seizing Opportunity in an Unpredictable World. Penguin UK. ISBN978-0-241-96351-7.[page needed]
^Stewart, Andrew (July 2004). "On risk: perception and direction". Computers & Security. 23 (5): 362–370. doi:10.1016/j.cose.2004.05.003. his finding is in alignment with risk compensation theory because it predicts that, essentially, skydivers will compensate for any new safety mechanism and consequently perform more dangerous types of jumping
^Holt, Martin; et al. (June 2018). "Community-level changes in condom use and uptake of HIV pre-exposure prophylaxis by gay and bisexual men in Melbourne and Sydney, Australia: results of repeated behavioural surveillance in 2013–17". The Lancet HIV. 5 (8): e448–e456. doi:10.1016/s2352-3018(18)30072-9. hdl:1874/377504. PMID29885813. S2CID47015652.
Wilde, Gerald J. S. (1994). Target Risk: Dealing with the Danger of Death, Disease and Damage in Everyday Decisions. PDE Publications. ISBN978-0-9699124-0-8.