Employment protection legislation (EPL) includes all types of employment protection measures, whether grounded primarily in legislation, court rulings, collectively bargained conditions of employment, or customary practice.[1] The term is common among circles of economists. Employment protection refers both to regulations concerning hiring (e.g. rules favouring disadvantaged groups, conditions for using temporary or fixed-term contracts, training requirements) and firing (e.g. redundancy procedures, mandated prenotification periods and severance payments, special requirements for collective dismissals and short-time work schemes).
There exist various institutional arrangements that can provide employment protection: the private market, labour legislation, collective bargaining arrangements and not the least, court interpretations of legislative and contractual provisions. Some forms of de facto regulations are likely to be adopted even in the absence of legislation, simply because both workers and firms derive advantages from long-term employment relations.[2]
Definition
According to Barone (2001) with the acronym EPL economists refer to the entire set of regulations that place some limits to the faculties of firms to hire and fire workers, even if they are not grounded primarily in the law, but originate from the collective bargaining of the social partners, or are a consequence of court rulings.[3] In particular, provisions favouring the employment of disadvantaged groups in society, determining the conditions for the use of temporary or fixed-term contracts, or imposing training requirements on the firm, affect hiring policies, while redundancy procedures, mandated pre-notification periods and severance payments, special requirements for collective dismissals and short-time work schemes influence firing decisions. The nature of these restrictions on the firms’ freedom to adjust the labour input is quite similar in all OECD countries, but the actual procedural details and the overall degree of stringency implied by them varies considerably. These provisions are enforced through the worker’s right to appeal against his lay-off.
Some aspects of these regulations, like the length of advance notices or the dimension of severance payments can be measured with precision. Other important features of EPL, like for example the willingness of labour courts to entertain appeals by fired workers, or how judges interpret the concept of “just cause” for termination, are much more difficult to quantify.
Employment Protection Legislation Index by the OECD
One of the more frequently used measures of the strictness of the EPL in each country and through different years is the so-called Employment Protection Legislation Index elaborated by the OECD. This index is calculated along 18 basic items, which can be classified in three main areas:[4]
Employment protection of regular workers against individual dismissal;
Specific requirements for collective dismissals; and
Regulation of temporary forms of employment.
The 18 first-digit inputs are then expressed in either of the following forms:
Units of time (e.g. delays before notice can start, or months of notice and severance pay);
As a number (e.g. maximum number of successive fixed-term contracts allowed); or
As a score on an ordinal scale specific to each item (0 to 2, 3, 4 or simply yes/no).
Then, these different scoring is converted into cardinal scores that are normalized to range from 0 to 6, with higher scores representing stricter regulation. Therefore, each of the different items is normalized according to weighted averages, thus constructing three sets of summary indicators that correspond to successively more aggregated measures of EPL strictness.
The last step of the procedure involves computing, for each country, an overall summary indicator based on the three subcomponents:
Strictness of regulation for regular contracts,
Temporary contracts, and
Collective dismissals.
The summary measure for collective dismissals is attributed just 40% of the weight assigned to regular and temporary contracts. The rationale for this is that the collective dismissals indicator only reflects additional employment protection triggered by the collective nature of the dismissal. In most countries, these additional requirements are quite modest. Moreover, summary measures for collective dismissals are only available since the late 1990s. An alternative overall index, so-called Version 1, has been thus calculated as an unweighted average of the summary measures for regular and temporary contracts only. While more restrictive than the previous one (so-called Version 2), this alternative measure of the overall EPL strictness allows comparisons over a longer period of time (since the late 1980s compared with the late 1990s).[5]
Effects of employment protection legislation
On the duality of the labour market
Some economists have claimed that empirical evidence gives support to their theories, according to which EPL leads to a segmentation in the labour market between the so-called insiders, the workers with a protected job, and the outsiders, who are people that are either unemployed or employed with fixed-term, part-time or temporary contracts, or even in the black economy, and face big difficulties to find a job covered by EPL because of the firms’ reduced propensity to hire.[citation needed] This latter group is mainly constituted by youths, women, racial minorities and unskilled workers.[3]
On unemployment
Whether EPL has any effect on unemployment is an issue of contention between economists. On the one hand, assuming that the cyclical wage pattern is not affected by mandated firing costs, EPL reduces the propensity to hire by employers, since they fear that such decisions will be difficult to reverse in the future, in case of a recession. On the other hand, EPL also leads firms during downswings to keep more workers employed, than they would have otherwise done. Therefore, EPL reduces both job creation and job destruction, so that the net effects on average employment and unemployment are not identifiable a priori. What is instead agreed among economists, is that more stringent EPL lowers the fluctuations in the quantity of labour demanded over the business cycle, leading to smoother dynamic patterns of those aggregates.[3]
Economists considering that EPL has no effect on unemployment include Blanchard and Portugal (2000).[6] In their article they compare two opposite countries as regards their EPL stance: Portugal with one of the more strict legislations in the world and the US with one of the more flexible ones. In spite of these differences, both countries have similar unemployment rates which undermines the argument considering that EPL has any effect on unemployment. Instead, the authors claim that EPL does affect two other variables: job flows and unemployment duration. EPL would reduce job flows (from employment to unemployment: employers are less willing to fire, given that they must pay indemnification to workers) therefore reducing unemployment but would increase unemployment duration, increasing the unemployment rate. These two effects would neutralize each other, explaining why overall, EPL has no effect on unemployment.
Nickell (1997)[7] arrived to similar conclusions when stating that labor market rigidities that do not appear to have serious implications for average levels of unemployment included strict employment protection legislation and general legislation on labor market standards.
Among those that have found evidence suggesting that EPL increases unemployment are Lazear (1990).[8] The author argued that mandated severance pay seemed to increase unemployment rates. His estimates suggested that an increase from zero to three months of severance pay would raise the unemployment rate by 5.5 percent in the United States.
On employment
Lazear (1990)[9] once again argues he has evidence suggesting that EPL reduces the employment-to-population ratio. In his article he claims that the best estimates suggest that moving from no required severance pay to three months of required severance pay to employees with ten years of service would reduce the employment-population ratio by about one percent. In the United States that would mean over a million jobs. Lazear argues that the young could bear a disproportionate amount of the burden.
To the contrary, Bertola and Bentolila (1990)[10] found evidence supporting the idea that firing costs have a larger effect on firms' propensity to fire than to hire, and therefore (slightly) increase average long-run employment.
On wages
Several authors have found that EPL has significant effects on wages. As stated by Lazear (1990),[11] in a perfect labor market, severance payments can have no real effects as they can be undone by a properly designed labor contract. Leonardi and Pica (2006) found evidence supporting this claim. They suggest that in the case of Italy an EPL reform in 1990 had as effect to reduce entry wages by 6 percent, implying that firms tend to transfer the increase in the cost of firing (due to EPL) onto workers. In fact, in their study they find that 25 percent of the firing cost was shifted onto lower wages in the case of Italy.[12] Similarly, Brancaccio, Garbellini, and Giammetti (2018) found that EPL reductions have no significant links with real GDP growth whereas they are significantly correlated with wage share reductions.[13]
On firm efficiency and profits
In principle the effects on profits are ambiguous. Because of EPL, firms engage themselves in labour hoarding practices, which lead them to employ a lower quantity of workers during upswings, while keeping inefficient levels of employment in downturns. For a given level of wages, this loss of productive efficiency would result in lower average profits. On the other hand, if firms
operated in a context of efficiency wages, by inducing more stable relationships with the workers and reducing their job and income insecurity, EPL could allow them to pay lower wages, without reducing the effort provided by the labour force employed, with beneficial effects on profits.[3]
On product market regulation
There appears to be agreement among economists on the positive correlation between product market and employment regulation. Although employment protection legislation is only one aspect of the wide range of regulatory interventions in the labour market, Nicoletti et al. (2000) find evidence suggesting that, across countries, restrictive regulatory environments in the product market tend to be associated with restrictive employment protection policies. They claim that the indicators presented in their paper are closely related, with a statistical correlation of 0.73 (significant at the 1% level). In other words, according to these results, restrictive product market regulations are matched by analogous EPL restrictions to generate a tight overall regulatory environment for firms in their product market as well as in the allocation of labour inputs. The strong correlation between regulatory regimes in
the product market and EPL also suggests that their influence may have compounded effects on labour market outcomes, making regulatory reform in only one market less effective than simultaneous reform in the two markets.[14]
Kugler and Pica (2003) find similar results in the case of the Italian economy. They present a matching model which illustrates how barriers to entry in the product market (product market regulation) mitigate the impact of labor marketderegulation, (that is, mitigate the effects of a reduction in the strictness of EPL). In the author's opinion, this means that there are economic complementarities between labor and product market policies in their model, in the sense that the effectiveness of one policy depends on the implementation of the other policy. Thus, an important implication of their model is that labor market deregulation will be less effective in the presence of heavier regulations of entry.[15] Similar results are obtained by Koeniger and Vindigni (2003).[16]
On hours per worker
Whereas EPL may have not a significant effect on unemployment, strict EPL gives incentives to the firms to resort to other sources of flexibility like overtime, which, as shown by Abraham and Houseman (1994),[17] indeed tends to be used much more in Continental European countries, where the variability of hours per worker is significantly higher than in the Anglo-Saxon labour markets.
Economic theory
In economic theory, several authors have argued that employment protection can be desirable when there are frictions in the working of markets. For example, Pissarides (2001) and Alvarez and Veracierto (2001) show that employment protection can play an important role in the absence of perfect insurance markets.[18][19] Schmitz (2004) argues that constraining contractual freedom by legislating employment protection can be welfare-enhancing when principal-agent relationships are plagued by asymmetric information.[20]
^OECD Employment Outlook, June 1999, Chapter 2, Employment Protection and Labour Market Performances, page 50.
^OECD Employment Outlook, June 1999, Chapter 2, Employment Protection and Labour Market Performances, page 51.
^ abcdBarone, Andrea (2001): Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature. Taken from www.cesifin.it [1]Archived 2007-09-30 at the Wayback Machine.
^For a detailed description of this procedure, see OECD, Employment Outlook 1999, Chapter 2, Annex 2.B.
^OECD Employment Outlook 2004, Chapter 2, Employment Protection Regulation and Labour Market Performance.
^Blanchard, O. and Pedro Portugal (2000): What hides behind an unemployment rate: Comparing Portuguese and U.S. labor markets. The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 1. (Mar., 2001), pp. 187–207.
^Nickell, Stephen (1997): Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 3. (Summer, 1997), pp. 55–74.
^Lazear, Edward P. (1990): Job Security Provisions and Employment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3. (Aug., 1990), pp. 699–726.
^Lazear, Edward P. (1990): Job Security Provisions and Employment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3. (Aug., 1990), pp. 699–726.
^Bentolila, Samuel and Giuseppe Bertola (1990): Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?. The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, No. 3. (Jul., 1990), pp. 381–402.
^Lazear, Edward (1990): Job Security Provisions and Employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(3): 699–726.
^Leonardi, Marco and Giovanni Pica (2006): Effects of Employment Protection Legislation on Wages: a Regression Discontinuity Approach. IZA Working Papers. Downloadable [2].
^Brancaccio, Emiliano and Nadia Garbellini, and Raffaele Giammetti (2018): Structural labour market reforms, GDP growth and the functional distribution of income. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics Volume 44, March 2018, Pages 34-45. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2017.09.001.
^Nicoletti, Giuseppe; Stefano Scarpetta and Olivier Boylaud (2000): Summary Indicators of Product Market Regulation with an Extension to Employment Protection Legislation. OECD Economics Department Working Papers NO. 226, April 13, 2000, p.51. Downloadable [3]
^Kugler, Adriana and Giovanni Pica (2003): Effects of Employment Protection and Product Market Regulations on the Italian Labor Market. Journal of Economic Literature, November 12, 2003, p. 7. Downloadable [4].
^Koeniger, Winfried and Andrea Vindigni (2003): Employment Protection and Product Market Regulation. IZA WZB Economics Seminar Series. July 28, 2003. Downloadable [5][permanent dead link].
^Abraham K.G. and Houseman S.N.(1994): Does Employment Protection Inhibit Labour Market Flexibility? Lessons from Germany, France and Belgium. In Blank R.M. (ed.) Social Protection versus Economic Flexibility: Is there a trade-off?. The University of Chicago Press, (1994)
^Alvarez, Fernando; Veracierto, Marcelo (2001). "Severance payments in an economy with frictions". Journal of Monetary Economics. 47 (3): 477–498. doi:10.1016/s0304-3932(01)00058-7. ISSN0304-3932.
^Schmitz, Patrick W (2004). "Job protection laws and agency problems under asymmetric information". European Economic Review. 48 (5): 1027–1046. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2003.12.007. ISSN0014-2921.
References
KG Abraham and SN Houseman (1994): Does Employment Protection Inhibit Labour Market Flexibility? Lessons from Germany, France and Belgium. In Blank R.M. (ed.) Social Protection versus Economic Flexibility: Is there a trade-off?. The University of Chicago Press, (1994)
Andrea Barone (2001): Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature. Taken from www.cesifin.it[5].
Samuel Bentolila and Giuseppe Bertola (1990): Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?. The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, No. 3. (Jul., 1990), pp. 381–402.
Olivier Blanchard and Pedro Portugal (2000): What hides behind an unemployment rate: Comparing Portuguese and U.S. labor markets. The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 1. (Mar., 2001), pp. 187–207.
Winfried Koeniger and Andrea Vindigni (2003): Employment Protection and Product Market Regulation. IZA WZB Economics Seminar Series. July 28, 2003. Downloadable [8].
Adriana Kugler and Giovanni Pica (2003): Effects of Employment Protection and Product Market Regulations on the Italian Labor Market. Journal of Economic Literature, November 12, 2003, p. 7. Downloadable [7].
Edward Lazear (1990): Job Security Provisions and Employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(3): 699–726.
Marco Leonardi and Giovanni Pica (2006): Effects of Employment Protection Legislation on Wages: a Regression Discontinuity Approach. IZA Working Papers. Downloadable [4].
Stephen Nickell (1997): Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 3. (Summer, 1997), pp. 55–74.
Giuseppe Nicoletti, Stefano Scarpetta and Olivier Boylaud (2000): Summary Indicators of Product Market Regulation with an Extension to Employment Protection Legislation. OECD Economics Department Working Papers NO. 226, April 13, 2000, p. 51. Downloadable [6]
Aquilinae adala subfamili terdiri dari anggota dari famili Accipitridae. Sistematik Image Genus Living Species Stephanoaetus Sclater, 1922 S. coronatus- Crowned eagle Nisaetus Hodgson, 1836 N. nipalensis- Elang mountain N. kelaarti- Legge's hawk-eagle N. bartelsi- Elang Jawa N. nanus- Elang Wallace N. alboniger- Blyth's hawk-eagle N. lanceolatus- Elang Sulawesi N. philippensis- Philippine hawk-eagle N. pinskeri- Pinsker's hawk-eagle N. cirrhatus- Changeable hawk-eagle N. floris- Elang Flores ...
Часть серии статей о Холокосте Идеология и политика Расовая гигиена · Расовый антисемитизм · Нацистская расовая политика · Нюрнбергские расовые законы Шоа Лагеря смерти Белжец · Дахау · Майданек · Малый Тростенец · Маутхаузен ·&...
Ini adalah nama Korea; marganya adalah Kim. TaeyeonTaeyeon pada Agustus 2019Nama asal김태연LahirKim Tae-yeon9 Maret 1989 (umur 35)Jeonju, Jeolla Utara, Korea SelatanPekerjaanPenyanyi Karier musikGenre K-pop R&B Dance-pop Balada Instrumen Vokal Gitar Tahun aktif2007–sekarangLabelSM EntertainmentArtis terkait Girls' Generation Girls' Generation-TTS Oh!GG Got the Beat SM Town SM The Ballad Situs webtaeyeon.smtown.com Nama KoreaHangul김태연 Hanja金太软 Alih AksaraGi...
American racing driver Kody SwansonSwanson in 2018 after winning USAC Silver Crown race at MadisonNationality AmericanBorn (1988-03-03) March 3, 1988 (age 36)Kingsburg, CaliforniaUSAC Silver Crown Series careerDebut season2008Wins40Best finish1st in 2014, 2015, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2021, 2022Finished last season1stChampionship titles2014, 2015, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2021, 2022USAC Silver CrownAwards2009USAC Silver Crown Rookie of the Year Kody Swanson (born March 3, 1988) is an American profess...
Final Piala Liga Inggris 1967TurnamenPiala Liga Inggris 1966–1967 Queens Park Rangers West Bromwich Albion 3 2 Tanggal4 Maret 1967StadionStadion Wembley, LondonWasitWalter Crossley (Lancaster)Penonton97,952← 1966 1968 → Final Piala Liga Inggris 1967 adalah pertandingan final ke-7 dari turnamen sepak bola Piala Liga Inggris untuk menentukan juara musim 1966–1967. Pertandingan ini diselenggarakan pada 4 Maret 1967 di Stadion Wembley. Queens Park Rangers memenangkan pertandingan ...
Public Park Middle Run Valley Natural AreaMain road-entrance to Middle Run Valley Natural Area, off of Possum Hollow Rd.Location of Middle Run Valley Natural Area in DelawareLocationNew Castle, Delaware, United StatesCoordinates39°43′2″N 75°43′22″W / 39.71722°N 75.72278°W / 39.71722; -75.72278Area850 acres (340 ha)Established1975Named forMiddle RunGoverning bodyNew Castle County, DelawareWebsiteNew Castle County Parks Middle Run, from between Poss...
Roller coaster at Disney parks Big Thunder Mountain RailroadBig Thunder Mountain Railroad entrance at Walt Disney WorldDisneylandPark sectionFrontierlandCoordinates33°48′47″N 117°55′13″W / 33.8130°N 117.9204°W / 33.8130; -117.9204StatusOperatingOpening dateSeptember 2, 1979 (1979-09-02)ReplacedMine Train Through Nature's WonderlandBig Thunder Mountain Railroad at Disneyland at RCDBMagic KingdomPark sectionFrontierlandCoordinates28°25′14″...
Hj. Nurbani YusufS.H.Nurbani pada tahun 1991LahirNurbani Yusuf Kantjasungkana(1939-12-25)25 Desember 1939Bengkulu, Hindia BelandaMeninggal22 Oktober 2015(2015-10-22) (umur 75)SingapuraKebangsaanIndonesiaAlmamaterUniversitas IndonesiaPekerjaanPengacaraAktrisModelSuami/istriKusumanegara (m. 1968, died)Anak2 Hj. Nurbani Yusuf Kantjasungkana, S.H. (25 Desember 1939 – 22 Oktober 2015)[1] adalah seorang pengacara, mantan a...
English princess Cecily of YorkViscountess WellesCecily in stained glass, probably 1482–83, formerly Canterbury Cathedral, now Burrell Collection.[1]Born20 March 1469Westminster Palace, London, EnglandDied24 August 1507(1507-08-24) (aged 38)Sandown, Isle of Wightor Hatfield, Hertfordshire, EnglandBurialQuarr Abbey, Isle of Wight orthe friary at Kings Langley, HertsSpouse Ralph Scrope (m. 1485; annulled 1486) John Welles, 1st Viscount Welles (m. 1487/88; died 1499) Sir Thomas Ky...
Students in Uganda. The system of education in Uganda has a structure of 7 years of primary education, 6 years of secondary education (divided into 4 years of lower secondary and 2 years of upper secondary school), and 3 to 5 years of post-secondary education.[1] Education in Uganda is administered in English. All throughout the levels in the education structure, modules are taught and assessed in English. The government of Uganda recognizes education as a basic human right and conti...
Ghazanchetsots Cathedral shellingՍուրբ Ղազանչեցոց եկեղեցու հրթիռակոծությունPart of the Second Nagorno-Karabakh WarLocationShusha, Nagorno-KarabakhDate8 October 2020 (2020-10-08)Injured11PerpetratorAzerbaijani Armed Forces[1] The 2020 shelling of Ghazanchetsots Cathedral took place prior to the Battle of Shusha on 8 October, when the Holy Savior Cathedral (Armenian: Սուրբ Ամենափրկիչ մայր տաճար, romanized:...
يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم في تطوير هذه المقالة من خلال إضافة مصادر موثوق بها. أي معلومات غير موثقة يمكن التشكيك بها وإزالتها. (ديسمبر 2018) سبورا لوكسمبورغ تأسس عام 1923 الملعب ملعب جوسي بارتيل البلد لوكسمبورغ الدوري دوري لوكسمبورغ الوطني&...
Presiden Negara Plurinasional BoliviaPresidente del Estado Plurinacional de BoliviaLambang BoliviaPetahanaLuis Arcesejak 8 November 2020KediamanPalacio QuemadoDitunjuk olehPemilihan umum langsungMasa jabatanLima tahunPejabat perdanaSimón BolívarDibentuk11 Agustus 1825WakilWakil Presiden BoliviaGaji$3.327 dolar AS per bulan[1]Situs webwww.presidencia.gob.bo Presiden Bolivia adalah kepala negara Bolivia. Urutan Presiden Mulai Menjabat Akhir Jabatan Catatan 1 Simón Bolívar Palac...
Audi A62018 Audi A6 50 TFSI quattroInformasiProdusenAudi AGMasa produksiC4: 1994 - 1997,C5: 1997 - 2004,C6: 2004 - 2011,C7: 2011 -Bodi & rangkaKelasMobil eksekutifBentuk kerangkasedan 4 pintu , Avant (estate/wagon) 5 pintuTata letakMesin longitudinal depan,Penggerak 4 roda, atauquattroPlatformPlatform Grup C VolkswagenMobil terkaitAudi S6Audi RS6KronologiPendahuluAudi 100 Audi A6 adalah sebuah mobil eksekutif yang dijual dan dipasarkan oleh pabrikan otomotif Jerman Audi AG. Audi A6 m...
Krivak-class frigate Menzhinskiy underway on 1 August 1985 History → Soviet Union → Russia NameMenzhinskiy NamesakeVyacheslav Menzhinsky BuilderZaliv Shipyard, Kerch Yard number201 Laid down14 August 1981 Launched31 December 1982 Commissioned29 December 1983 Decommissioned1998 Stricken2000 StatusRetired General characteristics Class and typeProject 11351 Nerey frigate Displacement 3,070 t (3,020 long tons) (standard) 3,545 t (3,489 long tons) (full) Length123 m (403 ft...
Le informazioni riportate non sono consigli medici e potrebbero non essere accurate. I contenuti hanno solo fine illustrativo e non sostituiscono il parere medico: leggi le avvertenze. Questa voce sull'argomento chirurgia è solo un abbozzo. Contribuisci a migliorarla secondo le convenzioni di Wikipedia. Questa voce o sezione sull'argomento chirurgia non cita le fonti necessarie o quelle presenti sono insufficienti. Puoi migliorare questa voce aggiungendo citazioni da fonti attendi...