Collectivization in Hungary

In the Hungarian People's Republic, agricultural collectivization was attempted a number of times in the late 1940s, until it was finally successfully implemented in the early 1960s. By consolidating individual landowning farmers into agricultural co-operatives, the Communist government hoped to increase production and efficiency, and put agriculture under the control of the state.

Post-War background

In early 1945, the provisional Hungarian government had appointed “land claimants” committees to examine the situation of the peasantry and develop a plan for land reform. When the proposed legislation was passed in March, it merely acknowledged the seizures the peasants had already undertaken.[1] Prior to the reforms, half of agricultural land had controlled by large, privately owned “hacienda-type” estates.[2] The provisional government legislation redistributed 35% of Hungary's territory, some 93,000 square kilometers of land.[3] While the wealthy who lost their land in the deal had obviously lost out, the problems of smaller peasant landholders were by no means solved. Many of them saw only slight increases in their property size to 11,000 square meters, “too small to provide a livelihood, let alone the basis for efficient agricultural production.”[4] These smallholders formed a political party which won a significant majority in the November election, but political maneuvering and election fraud by the Communists led to its failure in the following election.

First attempt at collectivization

While it remains unclear how the Smallholders Party would have solved the problems resulting from their dwarf properties, the plans of the Hungarian Working People's Party (MDP) soon became clear. The model of Stalinist collectivization would be adopted and applied with physical force if necessary. In July 1948, government regulations allowed the seizure of larger landholdings from nagygazdák (Hungarian [kulak]s). These regulations enabled over 800 square kilometers of land to be confiscated, 60% of which went to recently formed farming co-operatives, the rest going to private peasants.[5] This first serious attempt at collectivization corresponded with the first Five Year Plan, and both bore the marks of Stalinist agricultural policy. Both economic and direct police pressure were used to coerce peasants to join co-operatives, but large numbers opted instead to leave their villages. In the early 1950s, only one quarter of peasants agreed to join co-operatives.[6] Even once collectivized, farms were subject to harsh compulsory deliveries (production quotas in physical units passed down from central planning) and incredibly low agricultural producer prices. Although individual families were allowed a small private household plot intended to serve their own personal needs, decrees passed in 1949 and 1950 limited these plots with an absolute limit of 4,300 square meters, and its output was also subject to compulsory deliveries. The Five Year Plan initially promised 11 billion forints of credit for co-operatives (later downscaled to 8 million) but by 1953, less than half of that had been made available. Without credit from the government, or any reasonable ability to earn a surplus, peasants were unable to invest in their own farms and the co-operatives began to crumble.

Nagy's New Course and Rákosi's return

Although certainly not radical, Imre Nagy's “New Course,” introduced in 1954, promised an easing of social tension between co-operatives and the state. First, the compulsory deliveries were abolished, alleviating much stress for farmers. Second, the government devoted nearly one quarter of its national investment to agriculture and in just one year “more tractors were put into service than during the entire 1950-3 period.”[7] These new beginnings would not last long, however, as power struggles within the MDP in the spring of 1955 led to Mátyás Rákosi's return to power and a condemnation of the “right deviation” supported in the Nagy's New Course. Rákosi renewed the drive for collectivization, again using physical force to encourage membership. This attempt failed to last even as long as the previous drive. Nikita Khrushchev's secret speech and Rákosi's ensuing resignation led to second failure at collectivization. The weaknesses in the Stalinist model had been rather apparent to some after the first wave in the early 1950s, but the inflexibility of the Rákosi government left no room for any creative solutions.

1957 Agrarian Theses

After the events of the 1956 Hungarian Revolution and the re-establishment of political order, officials of the new Hungarian Socialist Workers Party (MSzMP) began to draw up a plan for a more gradual collectivization drive. Like Nagy's New Course, the changes suggested in the July 1957 Agrarian Theses were not drastic, but they made room for the possibility of further reforms. Some changes came almost immediately. The compulsory deliveries were not reintroduced and the purchasing prices introduced in 1957 were 80% higher than the compulsory prices had been.[8]

Tractors and machine stations

The government began to allow the co-operatives to purchase limited amounts of machinery for their own use. Until this point, all farm machinery had been kept in special state-run machine stations, but new regulations encouraged co-operatives to buy most forms of light machinery. By the end of the year, the 2557 existing agricultural co-operatives had purchased over 1000 light tractors.[9] In March 1958, Khrushchev suggested that machine stations had outlived their usefulness, and they were soon abolished. More purchasing of machinery was allowed the following year, and in 1961, a number of machine stations were allowed to sell off their obsolete machines. Furthermore, the machine stations in Turkeve and Székesfehérvár were converted into repair shops. Out of 235 machine stations in use in 1961, only 63 were open in 1964 and by the end of the decade, only a few remained in poor areas.[10] Most of the stations were transformed into repair shops to service the machinery quickly being acquired by the co-operatives. The new independent machine ownership would later spawn further demands by the collective farmers.

Household plots and sharecropping

Another shift that resulted from the Agrarian Theses was a new willingness on the part of Party to accept household plots belonging to members of co-operative farms. The acceptance of household plots grew primarily out of necessity; the infrastructure required to shelter livestock co-operatively could simply not be built quickly enough. The government adopted the common-sense solution of allowing members to keep animals on their household plots. The solution was a good fit. The farmers enjoyed the benefits of keeping their own animals (including milk, eggs, even calves and piglets) and the government avoided the unnecessary slaughter of animals that would have resulted from strict enforcement. Although the household plots had long existed, the idea of household stock-breeding was not approved of by everyone. In 1959, a report to the Political Committee worried that in some areas, local farm leaders continued to oppose the creation of household plots and made life difficult for those private owners. Government attempts push for tolerance of their measures stressed the “transitional” nature of the situation. In the summer of 1960, Lajos Fehér, Deputy Prime Minister, insisted that "...[h]ousehold farming is an integral complementary part of cooperative farming ... It will be needed so long as the economic activity of the co-operative ... has not reached a high enough level for collective production to take over the supply . . . In many places the transitional measures are being branded in a sectarian manner as 'capitalist tendencies' or regarded as some sort of 'sin or act against socialism' ... These damaging, narrow-minded ideas must now be forcefully eliminated, and everybody must understand ... the country needs meat!"[11]

Also allowed was the practice of sharecropping, in which co-operatively owned land was divided up between families and worked on relatively independently. The family would receive pay based on their work hours but also a percentage of the surplus from their particular strip of land. This helped to motivate members to work harder, particularly with crops like potatoes that required more manual labor. Both of these transitional measures integrated pre-soviet “family labor” practices with the ideal “socialist wage labor” to balance ideology with economic well-being.[12]

Resistance

With relatively little use of force, the great wave of collectivization occurred between 1959 and 1961, earlier than forecast in the Agrarian Theses. At the end of this period, more than 95% of agricultural land in Hungary had become the property of collective farms. In February 1961, the Central Committee declared that collectivization had been completed.[13] This quick success should not be confused with enthusiastic adoption of collective idealism on the part of the peasants. Private ownership meant independence and self-sufficiency, collectivization meant negotiation and uncertainty. Although pensions for members of co-operatives were a legal requirement after 1958, some elderly potential members were not convinced of the long-term financial security of co-operatives, and chose to leave their farms to seek industrial work where they were sure of a pension.[14] In the end, however, psychological factors might have been the deciding influence. Demoralized after two successive (and harsh) collectivization campaigns and the events of the 1956 Hungarian Revolution, the peasants were less interested in resisting, and as membership levels increased, those who remained likely grew worried about being left out.

Benefits

Whether or not peasants really wanted to join, the adjustments made to the agricultural system in 1957 clearly managed to satisfy the membership adequately enough that the co-operatives did not fall apart as they had in the past. Like Hungary, Poland and Czechoslovakia underwent a Stalinist phase of collectivization in the 1950s before leaving it behind in the search for a new model. In Poland, a sort of “dual agricultural” model was developed in which 20% of land was controlled by large, inefficient state farms, and the rest privately owned, mostly in the form of small peasant farms.[15] This isolated situation left the peasants open to obvious discrimination and they suffered from a lack of financial and structural support from the state. In Czechoslovakia, the state had only a bare tolerance for household plots and the transitional system was marked by its almost total inflexibility.[16] In contrast, transitional measures in Hungary worked with the concerns of the farmers, allowing them mechanical independence, semi-private production on their household plots and crop-shared fields, and a decent standard of living from higher agricultural producer prices and substantial government investment.

Drawbacks

With the ever-looming uncertainty of collectivization, Hungarian farmers became fearful and hesitant to purchase even simple tools to improve the production of their farms. They feared that their investment would be unable to be reaped by themselves, but would instead be used to benefit others. Additionally, many of the individual farms which operated before the collectivization attempts in the late 1940s and 1950s which were used for specific agricultural niches, such as horse-breeding and viticulture, for which there was a significant market, were changed to instead produce food crops. This, mixed with the inefficiency of the state-run farms, led to an overall decrease in production and profit for many farmers.[1]

See also

References

  • ^ Swain, RFFS, 35.
  • ^ Swain, CFWW, 3.
  • ^ Swain, RFFS, 35.
  • ^ Swain, RFFS, 36.
  • ^ Swain, RFFS, 42.
  • ^ Berend, 2
  • ^ Swain, CFWW, 27
  • ^ Berend, 106.
  • ^ Swain, CFWW, 37.
  • ^ Berend, 102.
  • ^ Berend, 98.
  • ^ Swain, CFWW, 33.
  • ^ Swain, CFWW, 4.
  • ^ Bell, 137
  • ^ Swain, Structures in Transition, 4.
  • ^ Swain, Structures in Transition, 4.
  1. ^ Balassa, Bela A. (1960). "Collectivization in Hungarian Agriculture". Journal of Farm Economics. 42 (1): 35–51. doi:10.2307/1235320. ISSN 1071-1031. JSTOR 1235320.

Sources

  • Nigel Swain, Collective Farms Which Work? (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985),
  • Nigel Swain, Hungary: The Rise and Fall of Feasible Socialism (London: New Left Books, 1992)
  • Nigel Swain, Central European Agricultural Structures in Transition (Discussion Paper for Frankfurt Institute for Transition Studies, 1999)
  • Iván T. Berend, The Hungarian Economic Reforms 1953-1988 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
  • Peter D. Bell, Peasants in Socialist Transition (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1984)

Read other articles:

Opposition to legal rights of lesbian, gay, bisexual, and transgender people Conservative Christian protesters against same-sex marriage at the U.S. Supreme Court after Obergefell v. Hodges (June 2015) Part of a series onLGBT rights Lesbian ∙ Gay ∙ Bisexual ∙ Transgender Overview Rights Movements Student Germany (pre-1933) United States Intersex rights Social attitudes Transgender rights Legal status Movement Aspects Decriminalization Marriage Legal status Timeline Migration Military se...

 

Copa Sudamericana 2003Copa Nissan Sudamericana de Clubes 2003 Competizione Copa Sudamericana Sport Calcio Edizione 2ª Organizzatore CONMEBOL Date 29 luglio - 19 dicembre Partecipanti 35 Risultati Vincitore  Cienciano(1º titolo) Secondo  River Plate Statistiche Miglior marcatore Germán Carty (6 gol) Incontri disputati 64 Gol segnati 164 (2,56 per incontro) Cronologia della competizione 2002 2004 Manuale La Copa Sudamericana 2003 venne vinta dal Cienciano nella doppia fi...

 

Mauritz von WiktorinWiktorin (kiri), Jenderal Heinz Guderian (tengah) dan Kombrig Semyon Krivoshein di pawai bersama Jerman-Soviet di Brest pada 22 September 1939.Lahir13 Agustus 1883Hainburg an der Donau, Cisleithania, Austria-HungariaMeninggal16 Agustus 1956(1956-08-16) (umur 73)Nuremberg, Jerman BaratPengabdian Austria–Hungaria Republik Austria Pertama Jerman NaziDinas/cabangAngkatan Darat JermanLama dinas1904–351938–44PangkatJenderal InfanteriKomandanDivisi Infanteri ...

Sauce made from the juices of meats For other uses, see Gravy (disambiguation). GravyStages in the preparation of mushroom gravyMain ingredientsJuices of meats that run naturally during cooking, wheat flour, cornstarch Cookbook: Gravy  Media: Gravy Gravy is a sauce often made from the juices of meats that run naturally during cooking and often thickened with corn starch or other thickeners for added texture. The gravy may be further coloured and flavoured with gravy salt (a simple mi...

 

Parliamentary constituency in the United Kingdom, 1885–1950 Bow and BromleyFormer Borough constituencyfor the House of CommonsBow and Bromley in London 1885-1918Bow and Bromley in London 1918-501885–1950SeatsOneCreated fromTower HamletsReplaced byPoplar Bow and Bromley was a constituency in the Parliament of the United Kingdom. Located in the Metropolitan Borough of Poplar in London, it was created by the Redistribution of Seats Act for the 1885 general election and returned one Member of...

 

Wiki carolina marin The Spanish National Badminton Championships is a tournament organized by the Federación Española de Bádminton to crown the best badminton players in Spain. The tournament started in 1982 and is held every year. Past winners Year Host City Men's singles Women's singles Men's doubles Women's doubles Mixed doubles 1982 Valladolid José Luis Carballido Margarita Miguelez Pedro V. BlachFernando Delgado Margarita MiguelezAída Carballal Pedro V. BlachLoli Alonso 1983 Madrid ...

Security Council Committee Established Pursuant to Resolution 1718 (2006)Formation2006, in response to North Korea's first nuclear test, and its continued nuclear proliferation efforts.FounderUN Security Council, in resolution 1718PurposeTo oversee the relevant sanctions measures relating to North Korea (DPRK)LocationNew York, USARegion Democratic People's Republic of KoreaFieldsEconomic sanctionsMembership All members of the UNSCParent organizationUnited Nations Security CouncilSubsidiariesP...

 

2013 live album by Barbra StreisandBack to BrooklynLive album by Barbra StreisandReleasedNovember 25, 2013RecordedOctober 11–13, 2012VenueBarclays Center, New York CityGenreVocalLabelColumbiaBarbra Streisand chronology The Classic Christmas Album(2013) Back to Brooklyn(2013) Partners(2014) Professional ratingsReview scoresSourceRatingAllmusic[1]New York Daily News[2] Back to Brooklyn is the eighth live album by Barbra Streisand, recorded over two nights at Barclays ...

 

LVIII campionati del mondo di ciclismo su strada 1985 Competizione Campionati del mondo di ciclismo su strada Sport Ciclismo su strada Edizione 58ª Organizzatore UCI Date 1º settembre 1985 Luogo Giavera del Montello Statistiche Miglior nazione  Francia Polonia Paesi Bassi Unione Sovietica (1/0/0) Gare 4 Cronologia della competizione 1984 1986 Manuale I Campionati del mondo di ciclismo su strada 1985 si disputarono a Giavera del Montello, in Italia. Furono assegnati...

Studio Bind Inc.Nama asli株式会社スタジオバインドJenisKabushiki gaishaPerusahaan patunganIndustriAnimasi JepangDidirikanNovember 2018; 5 tahun lalu (2018-11)KantorpusatSuginami, Tokyo, JepangTokohkunciToshiya OtomoTotal ekuitas¥ 5,000,000PemilikWhite FoxEgg FirmSitus webst-bind.jp Studio Bind Inc. (Jepang: 株式会社スタジオバインドcode: ja is deprecated , Hepburn: Kabushiki gaisha Sutajio Baindo) adalah sebuah studio animasi Jepang yang berpusat di Suginami dan di...

 

Former trade union of the United Kingdom General Union of Loom OverlookersPredecessorNational Confederate Association of Power Loom OverlookersFounded17 May 1885Dissolved2007HeadquartersBlackburnLocationUnited KingdomMembers 5,176 (1907)[1]8,820 (1933)[2]2,410 (1979)AffiliationsGFTU, Labour, NCTTF, TUC, UTFWA The General Union of Loom Overlookers (GULO) was a trade union representing junior supervisors in textile manufacturing in the United Kingdom. While most members were bas...

 

Liga 3 Banten 2023Negara IndonesiaTanggal penyelenggaraan8 Oktober – 31 Oktober 2023Tempat penyelenggaraan1 stadionJumlah peserta17 tim sepak bolaJuara bertahanSerpong City FCJuaraAdhyaksa Farmel FC(gelar ke-1)Tempat keduaPersikota TangerangTempat ketigaPersic CilegonTempat keempatPersipan PandeglangKualifikasi untukLiga 3 2023 Putaran Nasional← 2022 2024 → Seluruh statistik akurat per 11 Oktober 2023. Liga 3 Banten 2023 atau Liga 3 PSSI Banten 2023 adalah edisi keenam dari Liga 3 ...

Concert hall in Tel Aviv, Israel This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Heichal HaTarbut – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (March 2020) (Learn how and when to remove this message) Heichal HaTarbutFormer namesFredric R. Mann AuditoriumLocation2 Huberman StreetTel Aviv, Israel.Coordinates3...

 

French style of exuberant decoration For the Fabergé egg, see Rocaille (Fabergé egg). Commode decoration by Charles Cressent (1745–1749), Metropolitan Museum Rocaille (US: /roʊˈkaɪ, rɒˈkaɪ/ ro(h)-KY,[1][2][3][4] French: [ʁɔkɑj]) was a French style of exuberant decoration, with an abundance of curves, counter-curves, undulations and elements modeled on nature, that appeared in furniture and interior decoration during the early reign of Louis...

 

مروحة طميية هائلة تفترش الأرض الجرداء بين سلسلتي جبال كون‌لون وألتون اللتين تشكلان الحد الجنوبي لصحراء تكلامكان في شين‌جيانگ. الجانب الأيسر هو الجزء النشط في المروحة، ويبدو مزرقاً بسبب الماء المنساب في العديد من الغدائر الصغيرة. تصوير: NASA/GSFC/METI/ERSDAC/JAROS/ASTER مروحة طميية في و...

Chinese government agency managing finance Ministry of Finance of the People's Republic of China中华人民共和国财政部Zhōnghuá Rénmín Gònghéguó CáizhèngbùAgency overviewFormed1949; 75 years ago (1949)TypeConstituent Department of the State Council (cabinet-level executive department)JurisdictionGovernment of ChinaHeadquartersBeijingMinister responsibleLan Fo'an, Minister of FinanceDeputy Ministers responsibleLiao MinZhu ZhongmingWang DongweiAgency executive...

 

Municipality in Nordeste, BrazilBrejõesMunicipality FlagSealBrejõesLocation in BrazilCoordinates: 13°06′14″S 39°47′45″W / 13.10389°S 39.79583°W / -13.10389; -39.79583Country BrazilRegionNordesteStateBahiaArea • Total518.566 km2 (200.219 sq mi)Elevation611 m (2,005 ft)Population (2020 [1]) • Total14,222 • Density27/km2 (71/sq mi)Time zoneUTC−3 (BRT) Brejões is a muni...

 

建議此條目或章節與國際關係理論合并。(討論) 國際關係理論從理論角度研究國際關係;它嘗試為國際關係的分析提供理論框架[1]。奧利·霍爾斯蒂(英语:Ole Holsti)把國際關係理論形容為一副太陽眼鏡,讓配戴者只看到跟理論有關的重要事件。現實主義者認為無需理會的事件在建構主義者來說可能是具有關鍵性作用的,反之亦然。三套最盛行的理論分別為現實主�...

Sri Lankan politician Hon.Champika PremadasaMPMember of Parliamentfor Kegalle DistrictIncumbentAssumed office 2000 Personal detailsBorn (1948-11-04) November 4, 1948 (age 75)NationalitySri LankanPolitical partyUnited National PartyResidence(s)55/6 Water Tank Road, Rambukkana Abathenna Devayalage Champika Premadasa (born November 4, 1948) is a Sri Lankan politician and a member of the Parliament of Sri Lanka. References A.D. CHAMPIKA PREMADASA. Directory of Members. Parliament of Sri ...

 

American actor For the actor and dramatist who died in New York in 1889, see George Fawcett Rowe. This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: George Fawcett – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (April 2018) (Learn how and when to remove this message) George FawcettFawcett in the play The Great J...