A double auction is a process of buying and selling goods with multiple sellers and multiple buyers.[1] Potential buyers submit their bids and potential sellers submit their ask prices to the market institution, and then the market institution chooses some price p that clears the market: all the sellers who asked less than p sell and all buyers who bid more than p buy at this price p. Buyers and sellers that bid or ask for exactly p are also included. A common example of a double auction is stock exchange.
As well as their direct interest, double auctions are reminiscent of Walrasian auction and have been used as a tool to study the determination of prices in ordinary markets. A double auction is also possible without any exchange of currency in barter trade. A barter double auction is an auction where every participant has a demand and an offer consisting of multiple attributes and no money is involved.[2] For the mathematical modelling of satisfaction level Euclidean distance is used, where the offer and demand are treated as vectors.
A simple example of a double auction is a bilateral trade scenario, in which there is a single seller who values his product as S (e.g. the cost of producing the product), and a single buyer who values that product as B.
Economic analysis
From an economist's perspective, the interesting problem is to find a competitive equilibrium - a situation in which the supply equals the demand.
In the simple bilateral trade scenario, if B≥S then any price in the range [S,B] is an equilibrium price, since both the supply and the demand equal 1. Any price below S is not an equilibrium price since there is an excess demand, and any price above B is not an equilibrium price since there is an excess supply. When B<S, any price in the range (B,S) is an equilibrium price, since both the supply and the demand equal 0 (the price is too high for the buyer and too low for the seller).
In a more general double auction, in which there are many sellers each of whom holds a single unit and many buyers each of whom wants a single unit, an equilibrium price can be found using the natural ordering of the buyers and sellers:
Natural ordering
Order the buyers in decreasing order of their bid: b1≥b2≥...≥bn.
Order the sellers in increasing order of their bid: s1≤s2≤...≤sn.
Let k be the largest index such that bk≥sk (the "breakeven index").
Every price in the range [max(sk,bk+1),min(bk,sk+1)] is an equilibrium price, since both demand and supply are k. It is easier to see this by considering the range of equilibrium prices in each of the 4 possible cases (note that by definition of k, bk+1 < sk+1):
sk+1 > bk
sk+1 ≤ bk
bk+1 < sk
[sk,bk]
[sk,sk+1]
bk+1 ≥ sk
[bk+1,bk]
[bk+1,sk+1]
Game-theoretic analysis
A double auction can be analyzed as a game. Players are buyers and sellers. Their strategies are bids for buyers and ask prices for sellers (that depend on the valuations of buyers and sellers). Payoffs depend on the price of the transaction (determined by the auctioneer) and the valuation of a player. The interesting problem is to find a Nash equilibrium - a situation in which no trader has an incentive to unilaterally change their bid/ask price.
Consider the bilateral trade scenario, in which the buyer submits a bid of b and the seller submits s.
Suppose an auctioneer sets the price in the following way:
If s>b then no trade occurs (the seller wants more than the buyer pays);
If s≤b then p=(b+s)/2.
The utility of the buyer is:
0 if s>b;
B-p if s≤b (where B is the true value of the buyer).
The utility of the seller is:
0 if s>b;
p-S if s≤b (where S is the true value of the seller).
In a complete information case when the valuations are common knowledge to both parties, it can be shown that the continuum of pure strategy efficient Nash equilibriums exists with This means that, if B>S, there will be no equilibrium in which both players declare their true values: either the buyer will be able to gain by declaring a lower value, or the seller will be able to gain by declaring a higher value.
In an incomplete information (asymmetric information) case a buyer and a seller know only their own valuations. Suppose that these valuations are uniformly distributed over the same interval. Then it can be shown that such a game has a Bayesian Nash equilibrium with linear strategies. That is, there is an equilibrium when both players' bids are some linear functions of their valuations. It is also brings higher expected gains for the players than any other Bayesian Nash equilibrium (see Myerson–Satterthwaite theorem).
Mechanism design
How should the auctioneer determine the trading price? An ideal mechanism would satisfy the following properties:
1. Individual Rationality (IR): no person should lose from joining the auction. In particular, for every trading buyer: p ≤ B, and for every trading seller: p ≥ S.
Strong balanced budget (SBB): all monetary transfers must be done between buyers and sellers; the auctioneer should not lose or gain money.
Weak balanced budget (WBB): the auctioneer should not lose money, but may gain money.
3. Incentive compatibility (IC) also called truthfulness or strategy-proofness: also comes in two flavors (when unqualified IC generally means the stronger version):
The stronger notion is dominant-strategy-incentive-compatibility (DSIC), which means that reporting the true value should be a dominant strategy for all players. I.e, a player should not be able to gain by spying over other players and trying to find an 'optimal' declaration which is different from his true value, regardless of how the other players play.
The weaker notion is Nash-equilibrium-incentive-compatibility (NEIC), which means that there exists a Nash equilibrium in which all players report their true valuations. I.e, if all players but one are truthful, it is best for the remaining player to also be truthful.
4. Economic efficiency (EE): the total social welfare (the sum of the values of all players) should be the best possible. In particular, this means that, after all trading has completed, the items should be in the hands of those that value them the most.
Unfortunately, it is not possible to achieve all these requirements in the same mechanism (see Myerson–Satterthwaite theorem). But there are mechanisms that satisfy some of them.
Average mechanism
The mechanism described in the previous section can be generalized to n players in the following way.
Order the buyers and sellers in the Natural ordering and find the breakeven index k.
Set the price at the average of the kth values: p=(bk+sk)/2.
Let the first k sellers sell the good to the first k buyers.
This mechanism is:
IR - because by the ordering, the first k players value each item as at least p and the first k sellers value each item as at most p.
SBB - because all monetary transfers are between buyers and sellers.
EE - because the n items are held by the n players who value them the most.
Not IC - because buyer k has an incentive to report a lower value and seller k has an incentive to report a higher value.
VCG mechanism
A VCG mechanism is a generic mechanism which optimizes the social welfare while achieving truthfulness. It does so by making each agent pay for the "damage" that his desires cause to society.
In the simple bilateral trade setting, this translates to the following mechanism:
If b≤s then no trade is done and the product remains with the seller;
If b>s then the product goes to the buyer, the buyer pays s and the seller receives b.
This mechanism is:
IR, since the buyer pays less than his value and the seller receives more than his value.
IC, since the price paid by the buyer is determined by the seller and vice versa. Any attempt to misreport will make the utility of the misreporter either zero or negative.
EE, because the product goes to the one who values it the most.
Not SBB nor even WBB, because the auctioneer has to pay b-s. The auctioneer actually has to subsidize the trade.
In the general double auction setting, the mechanism orders the buyers and sellers in the Natural ordering and finds the breakeven index k. Then the first k sellers give the item to the first k buyers. Each buyer pays the lowest equilibrium price max(sk,bk+1), and each seller receives the highest equilibrium price min(bk,sk+1), as in the following table:
sk+1 > bk
sk+1 ≤ bk
bk+1 < sk
Each buyer pays sk and each seller gets bk
Each buyer pays sk and each seller gets sk+1
bk+1 ≥ sk
Each buyer pays bk+1 and each seller gets bk
Each buyer pays bk+1 and each seller gets sk+1
Similar to the bilateral trade scenario, the mechanism is IR, IC and EE (optimizes the social welfare), but it is not BB - the auctioneer subsidizes the trade.
The uniqueness-of-prices theorem[3] implies that this subsidy problem is inevitable - any truthful mechanism that optimizes the social welfare will have the same prices (up to a function independent of the ask/bid prices of each trader). If we want to keep the mechanism truthful while not having to subsidize the trade, we must compromise on efficiency and implement a less-than-optimal social welfare function.
Trade reduction mechanism
The following mechanism gives up a single deal in order to maintain truthfulness:[4]
Order the buyers and sellers in the Natural ordering and find the breakeven index k.
The first k-1 sellers give the item and receive sk from the auctioneer;
The first k-1 buyers receive the item and pay bk to the auctioneer.
This mechanism is:
IR, as before.
IC: the first k-1 buyers and sellers have no incentive to change their declaration since this will have no effect on their price; the kth buyer and seller have no incentive to change since they don't trade anyway, and if they do enter the trading (e.g. bk increases his declaration above bk-1), their profit from trading will be negative.
Not SBB, because the auctioneer is left with a surplus of (k-1)(bk-sk). But it is WBB, since the auctioneer at least doesn't have to subsidize the trade.
Not EE, because bk and sk don't trade, although buyer k values the item more than seller k.
If we tried to make this mechanism efficient by letting the kth buyer and seller trade, this would make it untruthful because then they will have an incentive to change their prices.
Although the social welfare is not optimal, it is near-optimal, since the forbidden deal is the least favorable deal. Hence the gain-from-trade is at least of the optimum.
Note that in the bilateral trade setting, k=1 and we give up the only efficient deal, so there is no trade at all and the gain-from-trade is 0. This is in accordance with the Myerson-Satterthwaite theorem.
Babaioff, Nisan and Pavlov[5] generalised the trade reduction mechanism to a market that is spatially-distributed, i.e. the buyers and sellers are in several different locations, and some units of the good may have to be transported between these locations. The cost of transport is thus added to the cost of production of the sellers.
McAfee's mechanism
McAfee[4] presented the following variation on the trade-reduction mechanism:
Order the buyers and sellers in the Natural ordering and find the breakeven index k.
Calculate: p=(bk+1+sk+1)/2.
If bk≥p≥sk, then the first k buyers and sellers trade the good in price p.
Otherwise, the first k-1 sellers trade for sk and the first k-1 buyers trade for bk as in the trade-reduction mechanism.
Similarly to the trade-reduction mechanism, this mechanism is IR, IC, WBB but not SBB (in the second case) and not EE (in the second case). Assuming that the values of the buyers and sellers are all bounded above zero, McAfee proves that the loss of trade efficiency is bounded by 1/min(num-of-buyers,num-of-sellers).[4]
Probabilistic reduction mechanisms
Given a p∈[0,1], after the bids are submitted, use the Trade reduction mechanism with probability p and the VCG mechanism with probability 1-p.[6] This mechanism inherits all the properties of its parents, i.e. it is IR and IC. The parameter p controls the tradeoff between EE and BB:
The loss of gain-from-trade is either 0 (achieved by VCG) or 1/k (achieved by trade-reduction); hence the expected loss in gain-from-trade is at most: p/k.
The auctioneer surplus is either negative (in case of VCG) or positive (in case of trade-reduction); hence the expected surplus is p*(surplus-in-trade-reduction)-(1-p)*(deficit-in-VCG). If the values of the traders come from known distribution, p can be selected such that the expected surplus will be 0, i.e. the mechanism is SBB ex-ante.
In a variant of this mechanism,[6] after the bids are submitted, the k-1 cheap sellers trade with the k-1 expensive buyers; each of them receives/pays the expected payment of the original mechanism, i.e. each buyer pays and each seller receives . Then, with probability p, buyer k pays and buys the good from seller k who receives . Like the first variant, this variant is IR and has the same expected efficiency and surplus. Its advantage is that it "hides" its randomized character from almost all traders. The downside is that now the mechanism is truthful only ex-ante; i.e., a risk-neutral trader cannot gain in expectation by misreporting his value, but after he knows the results of the lot, he might feel regret for not reporting otherwise.
SBBA mechanism
Segal-Halevi, Hassidim and Aumann[7] present a trade-reduction mechanism that is SBB, in addition to being IR and IC and attains (1-1/k) of the optimal GFT.
Comparison
Babaioff and Nisan[6]: Chap.4 provide both a theoretic comparison and an empirical comparison of the various mechanisms.
Modular approach
Dütting, Roughgarden and Talgam-Cohen[8] proposed a modular approach to the design of double auctions. Their framework views double auctions as being composed of ranking algorithms for each side of the market and a composition rule, and can be applied to complex markets. An immediate consequence of this framework is that classic double auction mechanisms such as the trade reduction mechanism are not only strategyproof but also weakly group-strategyproof (meaning that no group of buyers and sellers can benefit by a joint misreport of their preferences).
Beyond two categories
The basic double auction model involves two categories of traders: buyers and sellers. Babaioff and Nisan[6] extended it to handle a supply chain - a chain of markets, in which the buyers in one market become sellers in the next market. E.g., farmers sell fruits in the fruit market; juice makers buy fruits in the fruit market, make juice and sell it in the juice market to consumers. Babaioff and Walsh[9] extended it to handle markets in an arbitrary directed acyclic graph.
Gilor, Gonen and Segal-Halevi[10] study a multilateral market, with a set G of agent categories. he market is characterized by an integer vector r of size |G|, called the recipe of the market. Each trade in the market involves rg agents of category g, for each g in G. The standard double auction market is a special case in which there are two categories (buyers and sellers), and the recipe is r=(1,1). They present algorithms that are SBB, IC, IR and attain (1-1/k) of the optimal GFT. One algorithm is a direct revelation mechanism based on trade-reduction, and the other is an ascending-price mechanism that is not only IC but also obviously IC.
Gilor, Gonen and Segal-Halevi[11] study a more general multilateral market, in which there are multiple different recipes, arranged as a forest, where each recipe is a path from a root to a leaf. They present randomized ascending-price mechanisms that are universally IR, obviously-IC, SBB, and attain an asymptotically-optimal GFT.
See also
Supply-chain auction - a generalization of double auction to more than two agent categories.
Myerson–Satterthwaite theorem - no mechanism is IR, IC, BB and EE, even when there is only one buyer, one seller and one item.
^Tagiew, Rustam (22 May 2009). "Towards Barter Double Auction as Model for Bilateral Social Cooperations". arXiv:0905.3709 [cs.GT].
^Nisan, Noam (2007). "Introduction to Mechanism Design for Computer Scientists". In Nisan, Noam; Roughgarden, Tim; Tardos, Eva; Vazirani, Vijay (eds.). Algorithmic Game Theory. pp. 230–231. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511800481.011. ISBN978-0521872829. S2CID154357584.
^ abcMcAfee, R. P. (1992). "A dominant strategy double auction". Journal of Economic Theory. 56 (2): 434–450. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(92)90091-u.
^Babaioff, M.; Nisan, N.; Pavlov, E. (2004). "Mechanisms for a spatially distributed market". Proceedings of the 5th ACM conference on Electronic commerce - EC '04. p. 9. doi:10.1145/988772.988776. ISBN1-58113-771-0.
^Babaioff, M.; Walsh, W. E. (2005). "Incentive-compatible, budget-balanced, yet highly efficient auctions for supply chain formation". Decision Support Systems. 39: 123–149. CiteSeerX10.1.1.4.4123. doi:10.1016/j.dss.2004.08.008.
Missionsemblem Missionsdaten Mission ISS Expedition 15 Besatzung 3 Rettungsschiffe Sojus TMA-10 Raumstation ISS Beginn 9. April 2007, 19:10 UTC Begonnen durch Ankopplung von Sojus TMA-10 Ende 21. Oktober 2007, 7:14 UTC Beendet durch Abkopplung von Sojus TMA-10 Dauer 194d 12h 4min Anzahl der EVAs 3 Gesamtlänge der EVAs 18h 43m Mannschaftsfoto (v.l.) Sunita Williams, Fjodor Jurtschichin und Oleg Kotow (v.l.) Clayton Anderson, Fjodor Jurtschichin und Oleg Kotow ◄ Vorher / nac...
Kesultanan Utsmaniyah Nama Bendera Bintang dan Bulan sabit Pemakaian Bendera dan bendera kapal nasional Perbandingan 2:3 Dipakai 1844 Rancangan Bendera Merah dengan Bintang dan Bulan sabit putih . Varian bendera bendera nasional Kesultanan Utsmaniyah Nama Bendera Bintang dan Bulan sabit Pemakaian Bendera negara dan perang; bendera kapal negara dan perang Perbandingan 2:3 Dipakai 1793 Sepanjang berdirinya, Kesultanan Utsmaniyah menggunakan berbagai bendera, terutama untuk bendera kapal angkat...
Albert Walburton Squire Albert Warburton (26 Januari 1856 – 24 November 1925) adalah seorang mantan pemain sepak bola dalam era Victoria. Squire bukan merupakan gelar, namun merupakan nama pertamanya, meskipun ia dikenal dengan nama tengahnya.[1] Warburton merupakan kapten tim Blackburn Olympic saat mengalahkan Old Etonians pada Final Piala FA 1883 di Kennington Oval tanggal 31 Maret 1883. Referensi ^ Phythian, Graham (2007). Shooting Stars: The Brief and Glorious Hist...
Artikel ini sebatang kara, artinya tidak ada artikel lain yang memiliki pranala balik ke halaman ini.Bantulah menambah pranala ke artikel ini dari artikel yang berhubungan atau coba peralatan pencari pranala.Tag ini diberikan pada Januari 2023. MIS Al Wathoniyah Pusat PagiMadrasah Ibtidaiyah Swasta Al Wathoniyah Pusat PagiInformasiJenisSwastaAlamatLokasiJl. Raya Bekasi Km 17 Klender, Jakarta Timur, DKI Jakarta, IndonesiaSitus webMIS Al Wathoniyah Pusat Pagi pada Data Sekolah Kementerian ...
Uang logam 20 pence Irlandia Uang logam dua puluh pence (20p) (Irlandia: fiche pingincode: ga is deprecated ) adalah subdivisi pound Irlandia. Uang logam ini diperkenalkan pada 30 Oktober 1986. Koin ini adalah 1/5 dari pound Irlandia. Semua koin dua puluh pence ditarik pada tahun 2002 dengan munculnya euro. Pranala luar Situs web Irish Coinage - katalog - dua puluh pence desimal Coinage (Dimension and Design) Regulations, 1986 New Coinage (Twenty Pence) Order, 1986 lbsMata uang Republik Irlan...
Mazmur 23Naskah Gulungan Mazmur 11Q5 di antara Naskah Laut Mati memuat salinan sejumlah besar mazmur Alkitab yang diperkirakan dibuat pada abad ke-2 SM.KitabKitab MazmurKategoriKetuvimBagian Alkitab KristenPerjanjian LamaUrutan dalamKitab Kristen19← Mazmur 22 Mazmur 24 → Mazmur 23 (disingkat Maz 23, Mzm 23 atau Mz 23; penomoran Septuaginta: Mazmur 22) adalah sebuah mazmur dalam bagian ke-1 Kitab Mazmur di Alkitab Ibrani dan Perjanjian Lama dalam Alkitab Kristen.[1] Mazmur ...
Untuk tempat lain yang bernama sama, lihat Depok (disambiguasi). DepokKapanewonKantor Kapanéwon DepokNegara IndonesiaProvinsiDaerah Istimewa YogyakartaKabupatenSlemanPemerintahan • PanewuAbu Bakar, S.Sos, M.SiPopulasi • Total127,908 jiwa (per Desember 2.012) jiwaKode Kemendagri34.04.07 Kode BPS3404070 Luas35.55 km²Desa/kelurahan3Situs webdepokkec.slemankab.go.id Depok (Jawa: ꦝꦺꦥꦺꦴꦏ꧀, translit. Dhépok) adalah sebuah kapanéwon di Kabupaten...
Languages of the French territory Languages of New CaledoniaIndigenous languages of New CaledoniaOfficialFrenchIndigenousKanak languagesVernacularBislama, Tayo CreoleForeignEnglish, JapaneseKeyboard layoutAZERTY, QWERTY In New Caledonia, a sui generis collectivity of France, French is the official and predominant language. The collectivity is also home to about thirty New Caledonian languages, which form a branch of the Southern Oceanic languages. They are spoken mainly by the indigenous...
Artillery regiment of the South African Army This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: King Cetshwayo Artillery Regiment – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (January 2021) (Learn how and when to remove this message) Natal Field ArtilleryKing Cetshwayo Artillery RegimentSANDF Natal Field Artil...
Хип-хоп Направление популярная музыка Истоки фанкдискоэлектронная музыкадабритм-энд-блюзреггидэнсхоллджаз[1]чтение нараспев[англ.]исполнение поэзииустная поэзияозначиваниедюжины[англ.]гриотыскэтразговорный блюз Время и место возникновения Начало 1970-х, Бронкс, Н...
Misi diplomatik Papua Nugini di dunia. Berikut ini adalah daftar misi diplomatik Papua Nugini, tidak termasuk konsulat kehormatan. Amerika Komisi Tinggi Papua Nugini di Canberra. Komisi Tinggi Papua Nugini di London. Kedutaan besar Papua Nugini di Tokyo. Amerika Serikat Washington, D.C. (kedutaan besar) Asia Filipina Manila (kedutaan besar) India New Delhi (komisi tinggi) Indonesia Jakarta (kedutaan besar) Jayapura (konsulat jenderal) Jepang Tokyo (kedutaan besar...
كعكة سيخمعلومات عامةالنوع كعك تعديل - تعديل مصدري - تعديل ويكي بيانات كعكة المدخنة كعكة السيخ هي كعكة على الطراز الأوربي مصنوعة من طبقات من العجين أو الخليط المودعة واحدة تلو الأخرى على سيخٍ دائري أسطواني مدبب. تُخبز العجينة على نار مكشوفة أو فرن خاص أو مشواة. بشكل عام ، ترت�...
Indian actress (born 1982) This article has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page. (Learn how and when to remove these template messages) This biography of a living person needs additional citations for verification. Please help by adding reliable sources. Contentious material about living persons that is unsourced or poorly sourced must be removed immediately from the article and its talk page, especially if potentially libelous.Find sources: A...
Non-living object capable of carrying infectious agents A fomite (/ˈfoʊmaɪt/) or fomes (/ˈfoʊmiːz/) is any inanimate object that, when contaminated with or exposed to infectious agents (such as pathogenic bacteria, viruses or fungi), can transfer disease to a new host.[1] Transfer of pathogens by fomites A fomite is any inanimate object (also called passive vector) that, when contaminated with or exposed to infectious agents (such as pathogenic bacteria, viruses or fungi), can t...
Recommended activities and habits in Yoga Part of a series onHinduism Hindus History OriginsHistorical Hindu synthesis (500/200 BCE–300 CE) History Indus Valley Civilisation Historical Vedic religion Dravidian folk religion Śramaṇa Tribal religions in India Traditional Itihasa-Purana Epic-Puranic royal genealogies Epic-Puranic chronology Traditions Major traditions Shaivism Shaktism Smartism Vaishnavism List Deities Trimurti Brahma Vishnu Shiva Tridevi Saraswati Lakshmi Parvati Other maj...
Share of crimes which are alcohol-related Criminal activities that involve alcohol use Alcohol-related crime refers to criminal activities that involve alcohol use as well as violations of regulations covering the sale or use of alcohol; in other words, activities violating the alcohol laws.[1][2] Underage drinking and drunk driving are the most prevalent alcohol‐specific offenses in the United States[1] and a major problem in many, if not most, countries worldwide.&...
Huruf kiril U dengan makron Alfabet KirilHuruf SlaviaАА́А̀А̂А̄ӒБВГҐДЂЃЕЕ́ÈЕ̂ЁЄЖЗЗ́ЅИИ́ЍИ̂ЙІЇЈКЛЉМНЊОŌПРСС́ТЋЌУУ́ У̀У̂ӮЎФХЦЧЏШЩЪЫЬЭЮЯHuruf non-SlaviaӐА̊А̃Ӓ̄ӔӘӘ́Ә̃ӚВ̌ҒГ̑Г̣Г̌ҔӺҒ̌ӶД̌Д̣Д̆ӖЕ̄Е̃Ё̄Є̈ӁҖӜҘӞЗ̌З̱З̣ԐԐ̈ӠӢИ̃ҊӤҚӃҠҞҜК̣ԚӅԮԒӍӉҢԨӇҤО́О̀О̆О̂О̃ӦӦ̄ӨӨ̄Ө́Ө̆ӪҨԤР̌ҎҪС̣С̱Т̌Т̣ҬУ̃Ӱ Ӱ́Ӱ̄ӲҮҮ́ҰХ̣Х̱Х̮�...
James DuncanJim Duncan nel 1913Nazionalità Stati Uniti Altezza178 cm Peso86 kg Atletica leggera SpecialitàLancio del disco SocietàNew York Athletic Club Palmarès Competizione Ori Argenti Bronzi Giochi olimpici 0 0 1 Vedi maggiori dettagli Modifica dati su Wikidata · Manuale James Henry Duncan, detto Jim (New York, 25 settembre 1887 – 21 gennaio 1955), è stato un discobolo statunitense, vincitore di una medaglia di bronzo alle Olimpiadi di Stoccolma 1912. Indice 1 Carri...