Depending on author and context, the term "Carnegie School" can refer to either both branches or only the bounded rationality branch, sometimes with the qualifier "Carnegie School of organization theory". The commonality between both branches is the use of dynamic optimization and forecasting techniques derived from production theory, and the early use of computers to solve planning and optimization problems. Along with other, mostly Midwestern universities, the rational expectations branch is considered part of freshwater economics, while the bounded rationality branch has been credited with originating behavioral economics and economics of organization.[3][4]
GSIA was set up as a "new look" business school, moving beyond the case-based method of instruction popularized by Harvard Business School, to incorporate scientific methods of management. The economics faculty was folded into the business school.
In 1956, Carnegie Tech obtained an IBM 650 computer, jointly acquired by GSIA and the engineering and mathematics departments, but housed in the basement of the business school. Along with the computer, Allen Newell and Alan Perlis joined the faculty, with Perlis being put in charge of the computing facilities. Edward Feigenbaum, at the time a student at Carnegie Tech, was sufficiently intrigued to transfer to GSIA. All three, along with Herb Simon, would later receive the Turing Award for their contributions to computer science.
"The astonishing thing about Carnegie is that it joined two fundamental and seemingly incompatible strands of research. One dealt with bounded rationality, organization theory, and behavioral economics. The leading members of that group were Herbert Simon, Richard Cyert, and James March. The second strand dealt with rational expectations and efficient markets. Members of that group include Franco Modigliani (…), John Muth, Merton Miller, and Allan Meltzer, to be joined later by Robert Lucas (…), Thomas Sargent (…), and Edward Prescott." — Oliver Williamson[1]
People
“Carnegie Tech was an amazing place at the time. New ideas of all kinds were in the air. They were not always consistent with each other, as in the case of the conflict between John Muth’s suggestion about how to model expectations as “rational” and [Herbert] Simon’s notion of “bounded rationality.” We students benefited from the lively debates among the faculty. We were also encouraged by the faculty to get involved in the research process even before we had mastered the details of the literature. In my last two years, I took courses from Robert Lucas and Oliver Williamson with fellow student Ed Prescott, all of whom are now Laureates. In retrospect, it was obviously a very special educational experience.” – Dale Mortensen Nobel biographical (2010).
George Leland Bach (PhD University of Chicago 1940, economics) was the founding dean of GSIA when he was tasked in 1946 to restart economics education at Carnegie. He left in 1962 for Stanford University, with the brief to make Stanford’s business school look more like GSIA.
William W. Cooper (PhD unfinished Columbia University 1942, business) joined Bach from Chicago as the second faculty on the yet-to-founded new business school in 1946. Considered one of the founders of Management Science, jointly with his long-time collaborator Charnes. Became dean of the new School of Urban and Public Affairs in 1969, leaving Carnegie in 1975 for Harvard and later Texas. Herb Simon’s college dormmate.
Herbert A. Simon (PhD University of Chicago 1943, political science) joined the inaugural team of academics at GSIA in 1949, initially as the director of undergraduate programs. Stayed at Carnegie until his death in 2001, but left GSIA in 1970 for a joint psychology and computer science appointment. Received the Turing Award in 1975, jointly with Alan Newell, and the Economics Nobel Prize in 1978.
Organization theorists
Richard M. Cyert (PhD Columbia University 1948, economics) joined Carnegie in 1948, became Dean of GSIA in 1962 and president of Carnegie Mellon in 1972. Retired in 1990.
James G. March (PhD Yale University 1953, political science) joined Carnegie in 1953 out of graduate school, left in 1964 first for University of California, Irvine, then for Stanford University to help found the California tradition of organizational science.
Oliver E. Williamson (PhD Carnegie 1963, economics) wrote his dissertation under Cyert on managerial slack, left in 1963 for UC Berkeley and later Wharton, received the 2009 economics Nobel Prize (shared with Elinor Ostrom) for pioneering transaction cost economics.
Operations researchers and industrial engineers
Abraham Charnes (PhD University of Illinois 1947, mathematics) became a member of the GSIA founding team upon graduation in 1948. Joining up mostly with Cooper, they applied linear optimization to production and operations problems, somewhat apart from the Simon group. Left in 1955 for Purdue University, Northwestern University, and ultimately settled at University of Texas in 1968.
Charles P. Bonini (PhD Carnegie 1962, industrial engineering) at Carnegie as a graduate student from 1955 to 1959, joined Stanford University as junior faculty and immediately convinced Oliver Williamson to move in the other direction.
Publications
Highly influential books published by researchers of the Carnegie School include, in chronological order:
Theory of the Firm: Resource Allocation in a Market Economy (1965) by Kalman J. Cohen and Richard M. Cyert.
The Sciences of the Artificial (1969) by Herbert A. Simon.
Human Problem Solving (1972) by Allen Newell and Herbert A. Simon.
Bayesian Analysis and Uncertainty in Economic Theory (1987) by Richard M. Cyert and Morris H. DeGroot.
Models of Business Cycles (1987) by Robert E. Lucas, jr.
Decisions and Organizations (1989) by James G. March.
In addition to the books, a number of articles authored or co-authored by members of the Carnegie school became foundational within their fields.
"A Linear Decision Rule for Production and Employment Scheduling" (1955) by Charles C. Holt, Franco Modigliani, and Herbert A. Simon, Management Science.
"Dynamic Programming Under Uncertainty with a Quadratic Criterion Function" (1956) by Herbert A. Simon, Econometrica.
"Derivation of a Linear Decision Rule for Production and Employment" (1958) by Charles C. Holt, Franco Modigliani, and John F. Muth, Management Science.
"The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment" (1958) by Franco Modigliani and Merton H. Miller, American Economic Review.
"Forecasting Sales by Exponentially Weighted Moving Averages" (1960) by Peter R. Winters, Management Science.
"Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements" (1961) by John F. Muth, Econometrica.
References
^ abOliver E. Williamson (1996). "Transaction cost economics and the Carnegie connection". J Econ Beh & Org 31:2, pp. 149-155
^Esther-Mirjam Sent (1998). The evolving rationality of rational expectations : an assessment of Thomas Sargent's achievements. ISBN9780511528514.
^Raymond Augustine Bauer, Kenneth J. Gergen (1968). The study of policy formation. National Planning Association. p.115.
^Jens Beckert, Milan Zafirovski (2006). International encyclopedia of economic sociology. p.48