A Monetary History of the United States

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960
Dust jacket of 1st edition, 3rd printing
AuthorMilton Friedman, Anna Schwartz
LanguageEnglish
SubjectEconomic history
GenreHistory
Published1963
Princeton University Press
Publication placeUnited States
Media typePrint (hardcover)
Pages860 pp (first edition)
OCLC258805
332.4973
LC ClassHG538.F86 1963

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 is a book written in 1963 by future Nobel Prize-winning economist Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz. It uses historical time series and economic analysis to argue the then-novel proposition that changes in the money supply profoundly influenced the United States economy, especially the behavior of economic fluctuations. The implication they draw is that changes in the money supply had unintended adverse effects, and that sound monetary policy is necessary for economic stability. Orthodox economic historians see it as one of the most influential economics books of the century.[1][2] The chapter dealing with the causes of the Great Depression was published as a standalone book titled The Great Contraction, 1929–1933.[3]

Authorship

Friedman and Schwartz were working at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) when Arthur Burns, the future chairman of the Federal Reserve, suggested that they collaborate on a project to analyze the effect of the money supply on the business cycle.[4] Schwartz was already gathering much of the relevant historical data at that point, while Friedman was already a professor at the University of Chicago and also at the NBER. They began work in the late 1940s and eventually published A Monetary History through Princeton University Press in 1963. The Great Depression-related chapter, "The Great Contraction", was republished as a separate book in 1965.[5][6]

Content

The book discusses the role of the monetary policy in the U.S. economy from the Civil War Reconstruction Era to the middle of the 20th century. It presents what was then a contrarian view of the role of monetary policy in the Great Depression. The prevalent view in the early 1960s was that monetary forces played a passive role in the economic contraction of the 1930s. The Monetary History argues that the bank failures and the massive withdrawals of currency from the financial system that followed significantly shrank the money supply (the total amount of currency and outstanding bank deposits), which greatly exacerbated the economic contraction. The book criticizes the Federal Reserve for not keeping the supply of money steady and not acting as lender of last resort, instead allowing commercial banks to fail and allowing the economic depression to deepen.[7]

Themes

The book's main theme is the money supply. It tracks this through three numbers:

  • the ratio of cash that people hold in their checking deposits (when people trust banks, they deposit more of their money);
  • the ratio of bank deposits to bank reserves (when banks feel safer, they loan out more of their money); and
  • high-powered money (that is, anything that serves as cash or reserves).

The money supply (cash plus deposits) can be computed from these three numbers. The supply shrinks when people withdraw money from the bank, banks hold more reserves, or high-powered money leaves the country (e.g. gold is exported). During a crisis, all three can happen.

Another theme of the book is gold. For the time period, it was the unit used for international trade with Europe, so even when the United States is not on the gold standard (that is, paper money could be exchanged for bullion and international trade was settled immediately with gold), it plays a significant role. The authors write that the United States was on the gold standard from 1879 to 1923. From 1923 to 1933, the authors argue that international trade was "sterilized" by the Federal Reserve inflating the money rather than immediately being settled by gold. Lastly, they term the period from 1934 to 1960 (when the book was published) as a "managed standard". Paper money cannot be exchanged for bullion, and the authors compare gold to a subsidized commodity like grain.

Another book's theme is silver. China and Mexico used it for their currency and the United States used it for smaller coins. From 1879 to 1897, there was a populist push (bimetallism) to switch the gold-backed dollar to silver. The United States Department of the Treasury bought silver but that did not help when the country was on gold. Later during the Great Depression, the United States bought gold at inflated prices to help silver miners. According to Friedman and Schwartz, the result was tragic for the money supplies of China and Mexico.

In their book, the authors measure the velocity of money. While discussing this significantly, they ultimately did not make any conclusions about it. Lastly, another theme of the book is the decision making at the Federal Reserve. The authors also try to find out the people making the decisions and what information they had, perhaps just as important is the decision-making process. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York initially led the decision-making process but eventually migrated to the Federal Reserve Board in Washington, D.C. To a lesser extent, the United States Secretary of the Treasury's decisions were included.

Thesis

The thesis of Monetary History is that the money supply affects the economy. In the final chapter, they specify three occasions where the Federal Reserve acted strongly during relatively calm times and present these as an experiment for the reader to judge their thesis. The three actions by the Federal Reserve were the raising the discount rate in 1920, the raise of it in 1931, and the raise of the reserve requirement in 1937. Each of these actions caused a large contraction of the money supply over the next 12 months (9%, 14%, and 3%). In fact, these were the three sharpest declines they saw in their data. In those 12 months, industrial production fell dramatically (30%, 24%, and 34%), and other metrics fell at similar rates. These were three of the six worst 12-month periods for industrial production. The others were 1929−1931 (the Great Depression) and 1945, when the economy switched from wartime to peacetime production. Having demonstrated their thesis, they can now use it and argue that the Great Depression was due to the Federal Reserve letting the money supply shrink from 1929 to 1933.

Great Depression

Friedman and Schwartz identified four main policy mistakes made by the Federal Reserve that led to a sharp and undesirable decline in the money supply:[7]

  • In the spring of 1928, the Federal Reserve began to tighten its monetary policy (resulting in rising interest rates) and continued that same policy until the Wall Street Crash of 1929. This tight monetary policy caused the economy to enter a recession in mid-1929 and triggered the stock market crash a few months later.
  • In the fall of 1931, it raised interest rates to defend the dollar in response to speculative attacks, ignoring the difficulties this caused to domestic commercial banks.
  • After lowering interest rates early in 1932 with positive results, it raised interest rates again in late 1932, causing a further collapse in the United States economy.
  • The Federal Reserve was also to be blamed for a pattern of ongoing neglect of problems in the United States banking sector throughout the early 1930s. It failed to create a stable domestic banking environment by supporting the domestic banks and acting as lender of last resort to domestic banks during banking panics.

Influence

The book was the first to present the then novel argument that excessively tight monetary policy by the Federal Reserve following the boom of the 1920s turned an otherwise normal recession into the Great Depression of the 1930s. Previously, the consensus of economists was that loss of investor and consumer confidence following the Wall Street Crash of 1929 was a primary cause of the Great Depression.[citation needed]

The Monetary History was lauded as one of the most influential economics books of the 20th century by the Cato Institute book forum in 2003.[8] It was also cited with approval in a 2002 speech by then-Federal Reserve board member Ben Bernanke stating "the direct and indirect influences of the Monetary History on contemporary monetary economics would be difficult to overstate",[9][10] and again in a 2004 speech as "transform[ing] the debate about the Great Depression".[7]

The Great Depression-related chapter of A Monetary History was titled "The Great Contraction" and was republished as a separate book in 1965. Some editions include an appendix,[11] in which the authors got an endorsement from an unlikely source at an event in their honor when Bernanke made this statement:

"Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again."[12][13]

Monetarist economists used the work of Friedman and Schwartz to justify their positions for using monetary policy as the critical economic stabilizer. This view became more popular as Keynesian stabilizers failed to ameliorate the stagflation of the 1970s and political winds shifted away from government intervention in the market into the 1980s and 1990s.

Criticism

The book lays most of the blame for the Great Depression upon the Federal Reserve, arguing that it did not do enough to prevent the Depression. Economists such as Peter Temin raised questions about whether or not most monetary quantity levels were endogenous rather than exogenously determined as A Monetary History argues, especially during the Depression.[14] Paul Krugman argues that the 2008 financial crisis has shown that, during a financial crisis, central banks cannot control broad money, and that money supply bears little relationship to the GDP. According to Krugman, the same was true in the 1930s, and the claim that the Federal Reserve could have prevented the Great Depression is thus highly dubious.[15][16]

In The Golden Fetters, economic historian Barry Eichengreen argued that because of the then internationally prevailing gold exchange standard, the Federal Reserve's hands were tied. According to Eichengreen, in order to maintain the credibility of the gold standard, the Federal Reserve could not undertake actions (such as drastically increasing the money supply) in the manner advocated by Friedman and Schwartz.[17] James Tobin, while appreciating the rigor with which Friedman and Schwartz demonstrated the importance of the monetary supply, questioned their measures of the velocity of money and how informative this measure of the frequency of monetary transactions really is in order to understand the macroeconomic fluctuations of the early-to-mid 20th century.[18]

Murray Rothbard, an Austrian School and anarcho-capitalist economist, argued that the money supply actually increased during the time period where Friedman claimed the Federal Reserve contracted the money supply. He used this argument to say that the Great Depression was a manifestation of the Austrian business cycle theory. Both Rothbard and Friedman held the belief that the Great Depression was a result of the Federal Reserve.[19]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Michael D. Bordo; Hugh Rockoff (2013). "Not Just the Great Contraction: Friedman and Schwartz's A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960". American Economic Review. 103 (3): 61–65. doi:10.1257/aer.103.3.61. JSTOR 23469704. S2CID 154748046.
  2. ^ O'Sullivan, Mary A. (2021). "History as heresy: Unlearning the lessons of economic orthodoxy". The Economic History Review. 75 (2): 297–335. doi:10.1111/ehr.13117. ISSN 1468-0289. S2CID 244299719.
  3. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New ed.). Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  4. ^ Friedman, Milton (1989). "Collaboration in Economics". In Bordo, Michael D. (ed.). Money, History, and International Finance: Essays in Honor of Anna J. Schwartz. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press. pp. 248. ISBN 9780226065939.
  5. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  6. ^ Feldstein, Martin (April 14, 2000), "Remarks made by Martin Feldstein April 14, 2000 at a dinner honoring Anna Schwartz's 85th birthday", Anna Schwartz at the National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved March 15, 2011
  7. ^ a b c Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004). "Money, Gold, and the Great Depression". Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy. Federal Reserve Board website. Archived from the original on August 30, 2009. Retrieved August 19, 2009.
  8. ^ "A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960". Archived Events, Book Forum. Cato Institute website. Retrieved August 6, 2013.
  9. ^ Bernanke, Ben (November 8, 2002). "On Milton Friedman's Ninetieth Birthday". Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois. Federal Reserve Board website. Retrieved January 17, 2013.
  10. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929-1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  11. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  12. ^ Ben Bernanke (November 8, 2002), FederalReserve.gov: Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago
  13. ^ Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz; National Bureau of Economic Research (2008). "B. Bernanke's speech to M. Friedman". The Great Contraction, 1929–1933. Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0-691-13794-0.
  14. ^ Temin, Peter. "Review: Money, Money Everywhere: A Retrospective Review. Reviewed work(s): A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. By Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz." Reviews in American History, Vol. 5, No. 2 (Jun., 1977), pp. 151-159 (via jstor.org)
  15. ^ Krugman, Paul (May 1, 2012). "Milton's Paradise Lost". New York Times. Retrieved June 27, 2014.
  16. ^ Krugman, Paul (August 8, 2013). "Milton Friedman, Unperson". New York Times. Retrieved June 27, 2014.
  17. ^ Eichengreen, Barry J. (1992). Golden Fetters: the Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-506431-5.
  18. ^ Tobin, James (1965). "The Monetary Interpretation of History". American Economic Review. 55 (3): 464–485. JSTOR 1814559.
  19. ^ Rothbard, 1962, America's Great Depression

A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 at Google Books

Read other articles:

Часть серии статей о Холокосте Идеология и политика Расовая гигиена · Расовый антисемитизм · Нацистская расовая политика · Нюрнбергские расовые законы Шоа Лагеря смерти Белжец · Дахау · Майданек · Малый Тростенец · Маутхаузен ·&...

 

 

Alessia RovegnoRovegno pada parade LGTB+ di Lima, 2022.LahirAlessia Rovegno Cayo20 Januari 1998 (umur 26)Lima, PeruPekerjaanModelTinggi180 m (590 ft 7 in)PasanganHugo GarciaPemenang kontes kecantikanWarna rambutDark BlondeWarna mataHijauKompetisiutamaMiss Peru 2022 (Winner)Miss Universe 2022 (TBA) Alessia Rovegno Cayo (lahir 20 Januari 1998) adalah model, pemeran, dan penyanyi asal Peru. Ia merupakan pemenang Miss Peru 2022.[1] Sebagai Miss Peru, Rovegno akan mewa...

 

 

This article does not cite any sources. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Częstochowa Voivodeship – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (December 2009) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Częstochowa VoivodeshipWojewództwo częstochowskieVoivodeship of Poland1975–1998Location within PolandCapitalCzęstochowaArea •&...

Aerial view The Schinias Olympic Rowing and Canoeing Centre (Ολυμπιακό Κωπηλατοδρόμιο Σχοινιά) was built to host the rowing and canoe sprint events at the 2004 Summer Olympics in Greece.[1] It is the most northerly venue of the 2004 Games situated to the east of the town of Marathon. It covers 1.24 km2 and has a spectator capacity of 14,000.[2] It is a part of Schinias National Park. Although not fully completed until January 31, 2004, it hel...

 

 

Indomie Adalah Produk Mi Instan Di Indonesia Artikel ini membutuhkan rujukan tambahan agar kualitasnya dapat dipastikan. Mohon bantu kami mengembangkan artikel ini dengan cara menambahkan rujukan ke sumber tepercaya. Pernyataan tak bersumber bisa saja dipertentangkan dan dihapus.Cari sumber: Industri makanan – berita · surat kabar · buku · cendekiawan · JSTOR (Mei 2022) Komponen dalam industri makanan Industri makanan secara keseluruhan bukanlah satu i...

 

 

Artikel ini sebatang kara, artinya tidak ada artikel lain yang memiliki pranala balik ke halaman ini.Bantulah menambah pranala ke artikel ini dari artikel yang berhubungan atau coba peralatan pencari pranala.Tag ini diberikan pada Desember 2023. Valerie BergereThe Actors' Birthday Book, 1908LahirValerie Zenobia de Beaumont Lieb(1867-02-08)8 Februari 1867[1][2]Metz, Kekaisaran Kedua PrancisMeninggal16 September 1938(1938-09-16) (umur 71)Hollywood, California, A.S.Pekerjaan...

Перуанский анчоус Научная классификация Домен:ЭукариотыЦарство:ЖивотныеПодцарство:ЭуметазоиБез ранга:Двусторонне-симметричныеБез ранга:ВторичноротыеТип:ХордовыеПодтип:ПозвоночныеИнфратип:ЧелюстноротыеГруппа:Костные рыбыКласс:Лучепёрые рыбыПодкласс:Новопёрые �...

 

 

Identifier for a time offset from UTC of +02:00 Time zones of Africa: Light Blue Cape Verde Time[a] (UTC−1) Blue Greenwich Mean Time (UTC) Red Central European TimeWest Africa Time (UTC+1) Ochre Central Africa TimeEastern European TimeEgypt Standard TimeSouth African Standard Time (UTC+2) Green East Africa Time (UTC+3) Turquoise Mauritius Time[b]Seychelles Time[b] (UTC+4) a The islands of Cape Verde are to the west of the African mainland.b Mauritius and the Seychelles are to the east and n...

 

 

  كارابوبو   كارابوبو كارابوبو  خريطة الموقع الشعار (باللاتينية: Ocassus servitutis)‏  تاريخ التأسيس 1864  تقسيم إداري البلد فنزويلا  [1][2] العاصمة بلنسية التقسيم الأعلى فنزويلا  خصائص جغرافية إحداثيات 10°11′00″N 67°58′00″W / 10.183333333333°N 67.966666666667°W / 10.1...

この項目には、一部のコンピュータや閲覧ソフトで表示できない文字が含まれています(詳細)。 数字の大字(だいじ)は、漢数字の一種。通常用いる単純な字形の漢数字(小字)の代わりに同じ音の別の漢字を用いるものである。 概要 壱万円日本銀行券(「壱」が大字) 弐千円日本銀行券(「弐」が大字) 漢数字には「一」「二」「三」と続く小字と、「壱」「�...

 

 

Голубянки Самец голубянки икар Научная классификация Домен:ЭукариотыЦарство:ЖивотныеПодцарство:ЭуметазоиБез ранга:Двусторонне-симметричныеБез ранга:ПервичноротыеБез ранга:ЛиняющиеБез ранга:PanarthropodaТип:ЧленистоногиеПодтип:ТрахейнодышащиеНадкласс:ШестиногиеКласс...

 

 

Cuban baseball player (born 1989) In this Spanish name, the first or paternal surname is Hechavarría and the second or maternal family name is Barrera. Baseball player Adeiny HechavarríaHechavarria with the Omaha Storm Chasers in 2023Olmecas de Tabasco – No. 10ShortstopBorn: (1989-04-15) April 15, 1989 (age 35)Santiago de Cuba, CubaBats: RightThrows: RightProfessional debutMLB: August 4, 2012, for the Toronto Blue JaysNPB: April 30, 2021, for the ...

В Википедии есть статьи о других людях с такой фамилией, см. Френд. Руперт Френдангл. Rupert Friend Имя при рождении Руперт Уильям Энтони Френд Дата рождения 9 октября 1981(1981-10-09) (42 года) Место рождения Оксфордшир, Англия, Великобритания Гражданство  Великобритания Проф...

 

 

此條目需要补充更多来源。 (2021年7月4日)请协助補充多方面可靠来源以改善这篇条目,无法查证的内容可能會因為异议提出而被移除。致使用者:请搜索一下条目的标题(来源搜索:美国众议院 — 网页、新闻、书籍、学术、图像),以检查网络上是否存在该主题的更多可靠来源(判定指引)。 美國眾議院 United States House of Representatives第118届美国国会众议院徽章 众议院旗...

 

 

طالع أيضًا: تقويم قبطي هذه المقالة بحاجة لمراجعة خبير مختص في مجالها. يرجى من المختصين في مجالها مراجعتها وتطويرها. (أبريل 2014)Learn how and when to remove this message ورقة رزنامة جزائرية موافقة لأول أيام السنة الأمازيغية (عجمية) رزنامة لليوم الأول من السنة الأمازيغية الموافقة آنذاك ل 14 جانف�...

هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (سبتمبر 2023) غزو الغال في القرنين الرابع والثالث قبل الميلاد الشعوب في زمن الحرب البيسنتينية 269-267 ق.م على مدار ما يقرب من أربعة قرون من الزمن، خاضت الامبراطورية الروماني...

 

 

此條目没有列出任何参考或来源。 (2014年8月26日)維基百科所有的內容都應該可供查證。请协助補充可靠来源以改善这篇条目。无法查证的內容可能會因為異議提出而被移除。   地中海式氣候 地中海式气候   地中海气候 地中海式氣候,又稱作地中海氣候 (英語:Mediterranean climate)、副熱帶夏乾氣候 (英語:dry summer climate),其分布於中緯度地區(約南北緯30至40度�...

 

 

Manor house in Latvia Zante ManorZemgale, Latvia Zante ManorCoordinates56°50′09.4″N 22°43′55.3″E / 56.835944°N 22.732028°E / 56.835944; 22.732028TypeManor Zante Manor (Latvian: Zantes muižas pils) is a manor house in Zante, Zante Parish, Tukums Municipality in the Courland region of Latvia. In 1925 it became a school building. From 1953 to 1963 the manor housed the Zante secondary school, but it now houses the Zante primary school.[1] History Zante...

Deep-fried pastry of Chinese origin YoutiaoPieces of youtiaoAlternative namesChinese crullerTypeDonutCourseBreakfastPlace of originChinaRegion or stateGuangdongAssociated cuisineChina, Vietnam, Cambodia, Singapore, Malaysia, Indonesia, Philippines, Brunei, Myanmar, Thailand, Hong Kong and TaiwanServing temperatureFriedMain ingredientsDough  Media: Youtiao YoutiaoChinese nameTraditional Chinese油條Simplified Chinese油条Literal meaningoil stripTranscriptionsStandard Manda...

 

 

شرحبيل بن حسنة شُرَحبيل بن حسَنة، وشرحبيل بن عبد الله بن المطاع بن الغطريف[1]    معلومات شخصية الميلاد 40 ق.هـ 583مشبه الجزيرة العربية  الوفاة 18هـ 639مبلاد الشام  سبب الوفاة طاعون الأم حسنة أم شرحبيل  الحياة العملية المهنة وال،  وقائد عسكري،  وصحابة[1]...