Li Kwoh-ting (traditional Chinese: 李國鼎; simplified Chinese: 李国鼎; pinyin: Lǐ Guódǐng; 28 January 1910 – 31 May 2001) was a Chineseeconomist and politician best known as the "Father of Taiwan's Economic Miracle" and referred to by the New York Times as the "Godfather of Technology" in Taiwan for his work in transforming Taiwan's economy from an agrarian-based system into one of the world's leading producers of information and telecommunications technology.[1] His career spanned some 40 years, working for the Kuomintang government both before and after its defeat and subsequent retreat to Taiwan. His contributions continue to make him one of the most revered figures in Taiwanese history to this day.
He held a number of leadership positions in industry and government in Taiwan, including that of economic minister from 1965 to 1969 and finance minister from 1969 to 1976. After 1976 he was appointed "Minister without portfolio" and promoted science and technology in Taiwan.[3] In 1968, he received the Ramon Magsaysay Award for government service. He created a policy that helped attract entrepreneurs in the tech industry and helped fund Taiwan's electronics companies, which led to Taiwan's primacy as a producer of computer parts. Li had a very important role in the creation of TSMC, the world's largest chipmaker in 2023.[5][6] He also helped build the Hsinchu Science Park, which later became known as Taiwan's Silicon Valley. The park is one of the world's leading centers for semiconductor manufacturing and industrial and computer technology development. As of 2018 more than 500 high-tech companies reside in the park.[7] Li was also a senior adviser to the President of the Republic of China, Chen Shui-bian.[3]
Economic policy
In total, Li was a government official for 40 years, 10 of which he spent in mainland China before the Chinese Communist Party won the civil war. Tony Fu-Lai Yu speculates that the time Li spent in China, as well as his science-based university education, greatly influenced his policy-making in Taiwan. Li had no formal training in economics, thus most of his knowledge of economic management was gained from practical experience and working with other economists. Consequently, Yu argues his policy was insulated from popular economic ideology and instead was driven by pragmatism.[3] Li himself also claims that the purpose of his writings is to reveal his policy-making experiences for the future reference of other developing countries, and did not engage in writing about economic, administrative, or political science theory.[8]
Yu argues that Li's policy-making can be explained by evolutionary economics. Two Yale economists, Gustav Ranis and John C.H. Fei, wrote the introductory essays to Li's 1995 book The Evolution of Policy Behind Taiwan's Development Success. Therefore, it can be interpreted that Ranis and Fei's views on economic policy are representative of Li's.[3]
Ranis mainly writes on neo-classical growth theory, which claims that a steady economic growth rate can be achieved by correctly balancing the driving forces of labor, capital, and technology.[8][9] He also writes on the concept of agricultural labor surplus economies which, in freeing up workers and generating agricultural surplus and leading to increased productivity in expanding commercial sectors.[10][8]
Fei argues that two main types of forces govern policy evolution: objective and subjective. Objective forces are predetermined conditions, encompassing physical environments, external economic conditions, etc. Subjective forces include personal beliefs, economic knowledge, memories, experiences, and "common sense". Fei believes that political beliefs and ideology are the strongest factors in shaping economic policy-making, and thus is an ongoing process. In following with the concept of evolutionary economics, Fei believes that economic policy must change to suit new and ever-changing situations. Therefore, policy should not be static when created and instead evolve and be improved on to adapt to new situations.[3] Li himself claims that the liberalization of the Taiwanese economy was a gradual process rather than an abrupt one following the international popularity of free market thought in the 1960s and 1970s.[11]
Pragmatic economics
Li argues that there are two types of issues central to analyzing policy evolution. First is the economic impact of a policy, second is causation, or why a certain policy appears and is implemented at a certain time.[8]
Li believes pragmatism should supersede ideology in terms of policy-making:
[Policy innovation should be based on] the anticipation of impending problems and conflicts, rather than be purely ideologically motivated . . . The very notion of an evolution of policy suggests that the timing (or timely appearance) of a particular policy is important, and a good policy innovation is one that does not arrive prematurely. Ideological considerations often get in the way of appropriate timing as, for example, with so-called welfare state legislation that the economy simply cannot support. What can almost be called a rejection of ideology lies at the heart of a healthy pragmatism that has guided policymakers in Taiwan and has supported a social consensus for growth and economic liberalization.[8]
He argues against ideology-based policy making because it often interferes with the timing of certain policies, and all too often change too quickly. He believes such policy is "motivated by goals considered larger than people's actual well-being," which is a scathing review of ideology-based policy. Rather than ideology, Li believes the economic environment in which policies are made is more important and that policy should not be restricted by the ulterior motives of ideology-based economics.[8]
Policy revision
Li's trial and error policy making was made possible by Taiwan's flexible government policy. Li says that it made it possible to abandon or modify ineffective programs and easily create and implement new ones in reaction to new situations.[8]
Li's policies were often influenced by his experiences as part of the Kuomintang in mainland China. Hyperinflation was one of the major reasons that Chiang Kai-shek lost mainland China to the Communist Party, and thus Li abhorred all inflationary finance during his management of Taiwan's economy.[8]
His aversion to relying on inflation is apparent in his claim:
Taiwan's experience shows that fiscal reforms (tax legislation) and monetary reforms (moving toward central bank autonomy) are major evolu- tionary steps taken by a responsible government . . . What underlies both reforms is a rejection of the insanity of relying on the printing press to create purchasing power for the government to use in an effort to solve socioeconomic problems.[8]
Li indicates that this was the main difference between Taiwan's policy and those in Latin American countries, and that this method of managing the economy led to an overall more responsible government and transparent taxation system.[8] Li claims that during the 1950s–70s, the liberalization of Taiwan's economy was an unintended effect of their new policy, and it wasn't until 1983 that such "externally-oriented growth" was seen as beneficial and the merging of international competition in the domestic market was encouraged.[3] Furthermore, Li says that Taiwan's government was guided at the start with the principle that private property and a market environment which favored private businesses were to be encouraged.[8] Li writes:
Other promotional measures taken by the government included improving the investment climate, simplifying administrative procedures . . . providing necessary financing through banking institutions, and promoting investment and exports through tax relief and other incentives.[8]
This was the framework for Li's Principle of People's Livelihood[12] where the importance of protecting private property for the improvement of socioeconomic activities and establishing a free economy was only superseded by the need to expand state capital. Yu claims that this view falls under what Robert Wade calls the "guided market economy".[3] Li argues that the main problem with other less developed countries (LDCs) was that:
The alleged failure of the market in some other LDCs may, in fact, be due precisely to the opposite reason: the failure of political intervention in the market. Although the market structure was far from perfect at the beginning of transition growth in the 1950s, the overall trend has been for a strengthening of the market mechanism—a depoliticizing of the market. Taiwan experience shows that reduced intervention can work.[8]
Li argues that without the same willingness in developing countries to support a free market, Taiwan's economic miracles and history are useless to them.[3]
Government's role
Li explains that Taiwan's economic development was initially set back by the "scarcity of natural resources, shortages of capital and foreign exchange, technological backwardness, and lack of entrepreneurial skills," however, through the government's direct involvement and encouragement, the infrastructure and incentives needed for private enterprises to flourish, including mitigation of risk, was created:[8]
Among the major initiatives have been: the formulation of investment program and the provision of low-interest loans; the establishment of industrial zones, export-processing zones, and the science-based industrial park; Ten Major Development Projects, the Twelve New Development Projects and the Fourteen Key Projects in the 1970s and 1980s. The government also adopted various supplementary fiscal, financial, foreign-exchange, and trade-promotion measures to quicken the pace of industrialization.[8]
Taiwan's government made certain to not compete with private enterprises unless absolutely necessary, and the most lucrative investment projects were left for private businesses to take. Many times the government would first conduct feasibility studies before offering low interest loans to private entrepreneurs. Other times the government acted as sole owner of a business before handing it over to private investors.[3]
However, Li was a strong believer that it was important for the government to step back once the private sector became more established. Fiscal policy would then become more of a "stabilizing and equilibrating mechanism to counterbalance fluctuations in private economic behaviour. The evolution of fiscal policy in Taiwan has followed the same progression . . . with government intervention diminishing as the economy moved steadily in the direction of liberalization."[8]
This leads to Li's argument that there are two main major roles played by the government in economic development:
Enforcement of competition: To promote competition in small developing countries, it is best to open up the economy and expose domestic enterprises to international competition. Li believes anti-trust laws are superfluous in open economies. In new industries, government protection should only be given in the initial period.[3]
Identify the areas of production characterized by externality ("activities where the producers of the goods or services cannot easily charge those who benefit"--this is somewhat different from the common view of externality): Goods with external effect are not fixed and will mature with the economy. Thus, government operated sectors can become more privatized as the economy matures, although it is reasonably difficult to decide what the government should provide based on external economies, and therefore should remain an ongoing task.[3]
Transferability
On the topic of Taiwan's economic success being transferable to other developing countries, Li believes that:
...While our policy experiences cannot be transferred to LDCs as a whole package, individual measures (such as EPZs and investment incentives) that I introduced have, from time to time, been adopted successfully by neighbouring countries [...] If an experience can be transferable at all, the key question concerns the circumstances under which the policy is instituted. If the circumstances are too different, it is not likely that the policy will lead to the same result. The question of a policy's result is an economic issue, but the way policy is formulated is a political issue. Good economics can be rejected by bad politics. Hence, whether or not Taiwan's policy experience can be transferred to other developing economies depends very much on whether their cultures can allow pragmatism to overcome ideology as well as on how strongly they are dedicated to political and economic freedom.[8]
Although Taiwan experienced relative economic success over the course of its history along with the other Four Asian Tigers which employed similar economic policies as Taiwan, the lack of the same "miraculous" development in Latin American countries that employed the same principles brings into question whether Li's policies can be fully transferred and result in unequivocal success.[13] Li also did not consider external factors that helped Taiwan's initial economic growth, such as the economic and military aid provided by the US government from 1949 to 1965, which helped to dampen inflation.[13]
Economic achievement
Taiwan experienced GDP growth of 10.6% a year from 1965 to 1979 with no deterioration in income distribution, an improvement in literacy, a longer life expectancy than almost all other developing countries, increases in manufacturing earnings of 15% a year from 1960 to 1979, and unemployment at less than 2% since 1970. As of 1988, income per person was three to ten times higher than China. In 1953 Taiwan's per capita income was below the Mediterranean countries, and well below any Latin American country and Malaysia, whereas by 1982 Taiwan's per capita income had reached US$2500, much higher than Malaysia, Brazil, and Mexico, and on par with Portugal, Argentina, and Chile.[13]
In 1973 manufacturing's share in NDP was 36%, high even by standards of industrialized countries. Exports consisted of over half of GDP and consist of 90% of industrial goods, including textiles, clothes, leather and wood products, radio, television, cassette recorders, electronic calculators, sewing machines, machine tools, semi-conductors, and computers. This was a stark change from 1955's exports, which were 90% agricultural, consisting of mainly sugar and rice.[13]
Ian Little writes, "Government expenditure fell from 19.6% of GNP in 1963 to 16% in 1973, whereas [in 1979] revenue rose from 21% to 22.4%." According to Wade however, government expenditure as a share of GNP increased from 20% in 1963 to 23% in 1973 and to 27% in 1980–81. However, government revenue increased from 19.3% in 1963 to 25.8% in 1973.[13]
Criticisms
Taiwan's three-year stimulus package in 1991 to boost the private sector was NT $40 billion (US$1.5 billion) and included loans to small and medium-sized business and NT $20 billion for high-tech enterprises. The package also released 30,000 hectares of government owned land to the private sector, offered a five-year tax holiday to high-tech industries, allowed more foreign workers in to supplement the labor shortage in construction and manufacturing, and allowed more semi-finished industrial goods to be imported from mainland China to be processed in Taiwan. The goal of the plan was to maintain the expansion of Taiwan's GDP and private investment from falling below their then annual levels of 6–7% and 10–15%.[14]
Critics of the plan included those who worked in manufacturing companies, saying that, "The government's plans are so rough that at the industrial level we can't work with its programs." One such vice-president said that because large private-sector companies planned several years in advance, government policies that are vague and unpredictable can easily go awry. He adds that the amount of funding offered by the government "can't make a dent in what the private sector really needs."[14]
Other critics included businessmen who claimed the plan would only benefit big corporations and not the 97% of manufacturing companies that were small and medium-sized. They argued that the Cabinet was not counteracting the larger obstacle to private sector growth: the Central Bank's anti-inflation policy with high interest rates and tight liquidity. A manager of a computer parts company said, "It's easier to raise money in China than here."[14]
Furthermore, there has been considerable criticism on the viability of one "best practice" policy to which every developing country should adhere. Ha-Joon Chang argues that many already developed countries did not in fact reach their current development level through using the policies and institutions which they recommend, but in fact actively used "bad" trade and industrial policies, such as infant industry protection and export subsidies.[15] Chang proposes that many of the institutions which are regarded as necessary for economic development are the effect and not the cause of economic development. Chang concludes by suggesting that policies be catered to developing countries depending on their stage of development and needs, rather than by using a blanket set of policies.[15]
Legacy
Li's residence in Taipei is now a museum. The traditional 1930s style Japanese house was Li's home from 1972 to 2001. Taipei's former mayor, Hau Lung-bin, recalls fondly, "I was so impressed by its furnishings [...] They showed how prudent he was, and he read plenty of books and periodicals."[16][17] Additionally, to further honor Li, in 2011 an asteroid (239611 Likwohting) was named after him.[18]
^ abcdefghijklmYu, Tony Fu-Lai (March 2007). "The Architect of Taiwan's Economic Miracle: Evolutionary Economics of Li Kuo-Ting". Global Economic Review. 36.
^National Central University later renamed Nanjing University in mainland China and reinstated in Taiwan.
"歡迎進入李國鼎網站" [Kwoh-Ting Li—Taiwan's Road to Modernization]. Academica Sinica. Retrieved November 17, 2014. (in Chinese)
"李國鼎先生紀念網站" [The Kwoh-Ting Li Memorial Website]. Institute for Information Industry. 2001. Archived from the original on July 15, 2001. Retrieved November 17, 2014. (in Chinese)
"李國鼎科技發展基金會" [K. T. Li Foundation for the Development of Science and Technology]. Institute for Information Industry. 2014. Retrieved November 17, 2014. (in Chinese)
"財政人物索引: 李國鼎" [Financial Figures Index: KT Li]. The History of the Ministry of Finance, R.O.C online. Archived from the original on November 17, 2014. Retrieved November 17, 2014. (in Chinese)
Artikel ini tidak memiliki referensi atau sumber tepercaya sehingga isinya tidak bisa dipastikan. Tolong bantu perbaiki artikel ini dengan menambahkan referensi yang layak. Tulisan tanpa sumber dapat dipertanyakan dan dihapus sewaktu-waktu.Cari sumber: Garasi mobil – berita · surat kabar · buku · cendekiawan · JSTOR Bentuk garasi untuk dua mobil Garasi adalah tempat untuk menyimpan mobil agar terhindar dari pencurian ataupun untuk melindungi mobil...
Kamakura Maru datang ke Yokohama dengan abu dari empat pasukan kapal selam yang tewas dalam serangan di Sydney Harbour Sejarah Jepang Nama Chichibu Maru (1930-1938) Titibu Maru (1938-1939) Kamakura Maru (1939-1943) Operator Nippon Yusen KaishaPembangun Yokohama Dock Co., Yokohama, JepangNomor galangan 170Diluncurkan 1930Nasib Tenggelam, 28 April 1943 Ciri-ciri umum Kelas dan jenis Kapal penumpangTonase 17,526 GRTPanjang 1.707 m (5.600 ft 5 in)Lebar 226 m (741 ft...
Franceau Concours Eurovision 2023 Données clés Pays France Chanson Évidemment Interprète La Zarra Langue Français Sélection nationale Radiodiffuseur France 2 Type de sélection Sélection interne Date 12 janvier 2023 (artiste)19 février 2023 (chanson) Concours Eurovision de la chanson 2023 Position en demi-finale Qualifiée d'office en tant que membre du Big 5 Position en finale 16e (104 points) 2022 2024 modifier La France est l'un des pays participants du Concours Eurovision d...
Romawi Kuno Artikel ini adalah bagian dari seri Politik dan KetatanegaraanRomawi Kuno Zaman Kerajaan Romawi753–509 SM Republik Romawi509–27 SM Kekaisaran Romawi27 SM – 395 M Principatus Dominatus Wilayah Barat395–476 M Wilayah Timur395–1453 M Lini Masa Konstitusi Romawi Konstitusi Zaman Kerajaan Konstitusi Zaman Republik Konstitusi Zaman Kekaisaran Konstitusi Akhir Zaman Kekaisaran Senatus Sidang Legislatif Magistratus Eksekutif Preseden dan Hukum Hukum Romawi Ius Imperium Mos Maior...
Halaman ini berisi artikel tentang medali penghargaan militer. Untuk seri permainan video, lihat Medal of Honor (seri permainan video). Untuk permainan video, lihat Medal of Honor (permainan video 1999). Untuk permainan video 2010, lihat Medal of Honor (permainan video 2010).Medal of HonorMedals of honor versi Angkatan Darat, Angkatan Laut dan Angkatan Udara. (Dari kiri ke kanan)TipeMedali militer dengan pita leher(decoration)Diberikan kepadaKeberanian yang mencolok dengan risiko kehidupan di...
هذه المقالة تحتاج للمزيد من الوصلات للمقالات الأخرى للمساعدة في ترابط مقالات الموسوعة. فضلًا ساعد في تحسين هذه المقالة بإضافة وصلات إلى المقالات المتعلقة بها الموجودة في النص الحالي. (سبتمبر 2023) مسجد الشيخ بسطامي إحداثيات 36°29′03″N 55°00′01″E / 36.48425°N 55.000277777778°E / 3...
Rio BrancoCalcio Capa-Preta, Brancão, O Mais Querido Segni distintivi Uniformi di gara Casa Trasferta Colori sociali Nero, bianco Dati societari Città Vitória Nazione Brasile Confederazione CONMEBOL Federazione CBF Campionato Capixaba Série A Fondazione 1913 Presidente César Costa Allenatore Erich Bonfim Stadio Kléber Andrade (Cariacica)(21 152 posti) Sito web www.rbac.esp.br Palmarès Titoli nazionali 37 Campionati Capixaba1 Coppa Espírito Santo Si invita a seguire il mode...
Украинцы в Туркменистанеукр. Українці в Туркменістані Численность около 10-15 тыс. Язык украинский, туркменский Религия в большинстве случаев — христиане: греко-католики православные Украинцы в Туркменистане (укр. Українці в Туркменістані) — одна из этнических общин н...
Presbyterian creedal statement Title page of a 1647 printing of the confession Part of a series onReformed ChristianityReformation Wall in Geneva, featuring prominent Reformed theologians William Farel, John Calvin, Theodore Beza, and John Knox Background Christianity Reformation Protestantism Theology Theology of John Calvin Covenant theology Republication of the Covenant of Works Baptist Covenant Theology Logical order of God's decrees Baptism Lord's Supper Regulative principle Predestinati...
artikel ini perlu dirapikan agar memenuhi standar Wikipedia. Tidak ada alasan yang diberikan. Silakan kembangkan artikel ini semampu Anda. Merapikan artikel dapat dilakukan dengan wikifikasi atau membagi artikel ke paragraf-paragraf. Jika sudah dirapikan, silakan hapus templat ini. (Pelajari cara dan kapan saatnya untuk menghapus pesan templat ini) A ProphetPoster rilis teatrikalSutradaraJacques AudiardProduser Martine Cassinelli Antonin Dedet Ditulis oleh Jacques Audiard Thomas Bidegain Abde...
Street intersection in Manhattan, New York For the television series, see Foley Square (TV series). Triumph of the Human Spirit at Foley Square in 2019 Foley Square, also called Federal Plaza,[1] is a street intersection in the Civic Center neighborhood of Lower Manhattan, New York City, which contains a small triangular park named Thomas Paine Park.[2] The space is bordered by Worth Street to the north, Centre Street to the east, and Lafayette Street to the west, and is locat...
Protein-coding gene in the species Homo sapiens GPRC5DIdentifiersAliasesGPRC5D, G protein-coupled receptor, class C, group 5, member D, G protein-coupled receptor class C group 5 member DExternal IDsOMIM: 607437 MGI: 1935037 HomoloGene: 10250 GeneCards: GPRC5D Gene location (Human)Chr.Chromosome 12 (human)[1]Band12p13.1Start12,940,575 bp[1]End12,952,170 bp[1]Gene location (Mouse)Chr.Chromosome 6 (mouse)[2]Band6|6 G1Start135,082,989 bp[2]End135,095,...
Reuse of scrap aluminium An aluminium recycling symbol. The European Committee for Standardization logo for aluminium recycling. Aluminium recycling is the process in which secondary commercial aluminium is created from scrap or other forms of end-of-life or otherwise unusable aluminium.[1] It involves re-melting the metal, which is cheaper and more energy-efficient than the production of virgin aluminium by electrolysis of alumina (Al2O3) refined from raw bauxite by use of the Bayer ...
Ne doit pas être confondu avec Grégoire de Nicée. Grégoire de Nysse Saint chrétien Saint Grégoire de Nysse, fresque du XIVe siècle, église Saint-Sauveur-in-Chora, Istanbul. évêque, Père de l'Église (cappadocien) Naissance v. 335Néocésarée (Niksar), Empire Romain d'Orient Décès v. 395 (aux alentours de 60 ans) Nysse, Empire byzantin Vénéré par Église catholiqueÉglise orthodoxe Fête 10 janvier modifier Grégoire de Nysse, (en grec ancien : Γρηγ�...
Type of spinal cancer Not to be confused with Chondroma. Medical conditionChordomaMRI of extensive clival chordoma in 17-year-old male patient, axial view. Tumor in the nasopharynx extending from nasal cavity to brainstem posteriorly is clearly visible.SpecialtyOncology Chordoma is a rare slow-growing neoplasm thought to arise from cellular remnants of the notochord. The evidence for this is the location of the tumors (along the neuraxis), the similar immunohistochemical staining patter...
County in Wyoming, United States County in WyomingWeston CountyCountyWeston County Courthouse in Newcastle FlagLocation within the U.S. state of WyomingWyoming's location within the U.S.Coordinates: 43°50′N 104°34′W / 43.84°N 104.56°W / 43.84; -104.56Country United StatesState WyomingFoundedMarch 12, 1890Named forJefferson B. WestonSeatNewcastleLargest cityNewcastleArea • Total2,400 sq mi (6,000 km2) • Land2,398&...
Transparent display presenting data within normal sight lines of the user This article is about the military and vehicle technology. For its use in gaming, see HUD (video gaming). HUD of an F/A-18 Hornet A head-up display, or heads-up display,[1] also known as a HUD (/hʌd/) or head-up guidance system (HGS), is any transparent display that presents data without requiring users to look away from their usual viewpoints. The origin of the name stems from a pilot being able to view inform...